The World’s Largest Open Access Agricultural & Applied Economics Digital Library
This document is discoverable and free to researchers across the
globe due to the work of AgEcon Search.
Help ensure our sustainability.
Give to AgEcon Search
AgEcon Search
https://ageconsearch.umn.edu
[email protected]
Papers downloaded from AgEcon Search may be used for non-commercial purposes and personal study only.
No other use, including posting to another Internet site, is permitted without permission from the copyright
owner (not AgEcon Search), or as allowed under the provisions of Fair Use, U.S. Copyright Act, Title 17 U.S.C.
Environment, Human Development
and Economic Growth
Valeria Costantini and Salvatore Monni
NOTA DI LAVORO 35.2006
FEBRUARY 2006
IEM – International Energy Markets
Valeria Costantini and Salvatore Monni, Department of Economics, Roma Tre University
This paper can be downloaded without charge at:
The Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Note di Lavoro Series Index:
https://www.feem.it/Feem/Pub/Publications/WPapers/default.htm
Social Science Research Network Electronic Paper Collection:
https://ssrn.com/abstract=888775
The opinions expressed in this paper do not necessarily reflect the position of
Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei
Corso Magenta, 63, 20123 Milano (I), web site: www.feem.it, e-mail:
[email protected]
Environment, Human Development and Economic Growth
Summary
Over the last few years, environmental issues have entered into policy design,
particularly development and growth policies. Natural resources are considered
necessary production inputs and environmental quality is considered a welfare
determinant. The integration of environmental issues into economic growth and
development theories and empirics is currently widely analyzed in the literature. The
effects of natural resources endowment on economic growth are mainly analyzed
through the so-called Resource Curse Hypothesis (RCH) whereas the effects of
economic growth on environmental quality are part of the Environmental Kuznets
Curve (EKC). Furthermore, recent contributions on RCH and EKC have shown the
important role of institutions and human development dimensions in building a
sustainable development path. In this paper, we attempt to analyze the causal
relationships between economic growth, human development and sustainability
combining the RCH and EKC models and adopting a human development perspective.
Keywords: Natural Resources, Sustainability, Human Development, Trade
JEL Classification: O15, Q01, Q56
We are grateful to Anantha Duraiappah and the other participants to the HDCAUNESCO Conference “Knowledge in Public Action: Education, Responsibility,
Collective Agency, Equity”, Paris, September 2005, and Fabrizio De Filippis and an
anonymous referee for useful comments and suggestions to a first version of this paper.
Address for correspondence:
Valeria Costantini
Department of Economic
Roma Tre University
Roma
Italy
Phone: +39 06 57374215
E-mail:
[email protected]
1. INTRODUCTION
Over the last decades, development thinking has been profoundly changed by two
different, albeit complementary, issues that emerged in the international literature: the
concepts of human development (HD) and sustainable development (SD).
The definition of a widely known concept of human well-being based on the capability
approach formulated by Sen (1979, 1982, 1983, 1985) was the basis of the first Human
Development Report published by UNDP in 1990.1 The HD paradigm developed by
UNDP focused its attention on how development could enlarge people’s choices by
expanding freedoms and capabilities.
Moreover, HD also means an expansion of the real freedom that individuals enjoy and
attention must be shifted away from the means that allow liberties to expand such as
economic growth, increased personal income, technological progress or social
modernization towards the ends which are the liberties themselves (Sen, 1999).
Over the last years, a great deal of attention has also been given to the role of natural
resources and the environment, fundamental aspects of human well-being and the
quality of life. Attention has gradually shifted from a vision of environment as a limit to
economic growth (Meadows et al., 1972) to its active role in reducing poverty, achieving
higher living standards and increasing human development levels. As claimed by the
Brundtland Report, the definition of SD requires the same level of well-being achieved
for the present generation to be maintained for future generations (WCED, 1987).
The first Human Development Reports have not explicitly considered the role of the
natural environment in enhancing people’s choices but in more recent editions, the
environment and more broadly sustainable development have been progressively
introduced (UNDP, 1996). In the year 2000, the definition of the Millennium
Development Goals by the United Nations definitively recognized the full integration of
human development and the environment as mutually reinforcing development goals.
“The capability approach is a broad normative framework for the evaluation and assessment of
individual well-being and social arrangements, the design of policies, and proposals for social change in
society. […] It can be used to evaluate several aspects of people’s well-being such as inequality, poverty,
the well-being of an individual or the average well-being of members of a group. It can also be used as an
alternative evaluative tool for social cost-benefit analysis or to design and evaluate policies ranging from
welfare state design in affluent societies to development policies by governments and non-governmental
organisations in developing countries.” (Robeyens, 2005, p. 94).
1
1
From a theoretical perspective, an integrated Sustainable Human Development paradigm
has been defined as development that promotes the capabilities of people in the present
without compromising the capabilities of future generations (Sen, 2000).2
Two different approaches seem to be the most appealing for this integrated paradigm.
The effects of natural resources endowment on development are mainly analysed
through the so-called Resource Curse Hypothesis (RCH) whereas the effects of
economic growth and development process on environmental quality are part of the
Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC).
There are many empirical contributions that analyze the role of natural resources
endowments in the economic growth process and define the so-called Resource Curse
Hypothesis (RCH). The scope of these analyses is to capture the positive or negative role
of natural resources in enhancing or reducing economic growth rate. The empirical
models of RCH adopt both the convergence theory developed by Barro and Sala-iMartin (1995) and the huge amount of literature that analyzes the causal relationships
between trade openness (and more broadly globalization) and economic growth.
Furthermore, the specific role of human capital accumulation (related especially to
education) and the quality of institutions has been introduced as a further explanation of
the resource curse.
It is worth noting that the role of trade and economic globalization – defined as a
process of enlarging opportunities in terms of new technologies, such as information,
communication and competitiveness (Bhagwati, 2004), – is particularly important in all
the explanations proposed as the basis of the RCH. The influence of the exploitation of
natural resources on economic growth must be linked to the export flows of such
primary resources and the role of innovation technology and foreign direct investment
are equally recognized. Most of the RCH contributions explicitly relate to the tradegrowth literature which analyzes links between trade liberalization and economic growth
(Frankel and Romer, 1999; Winters, 2004), with specific effects on poverty and income
distribution (Dollar and Kraay, 2004; Ravallion, 2001, 2003), or specific issues related to
the role of institutions (North, 1990; Rodriguez and Rodrik, 2001; Rodrik, 1998, 2000;
Sokoloff and Engerman, 2000) and the effects on developing countries (Acemoglu et al.,
2001; Greenaway et al., 2002; Martin, 2001; Moseley, 2000). The RCH literature has
2 For an empirical survey on measurement of Sustainable Human Development, see Costantini and Monni
(2005).
2
made a further step forward by including natural resources endowment as a possible
source of low growth rate together with trade restrictive policies, macroeconomic
instability, low human capital accumulation rate, corruption and so on.
The opposite causal relationship - the effects of economic growth and development on
the environmental quality – has been mainly analyzed through the so-called
Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC). Pioneering contributions stressed the importance
of pure economic growth (in terms of income per capita) as a major source of
environmental degradation (Grossman and Krueger, 1995; Shafik, 1994) whereas recent
contributions have shown the important role played by further aspects related to
globalization, health, education and other well-being dimensions (Hill and Magnani,
2002; Tisdell, 2001).
It seems clear that both the RCH and the EKC models are deeply influenced by human
development dimensions and such a common element could be a useful link between
the two causal relationships. Furthermore, the role of globalization is a necessary
additional perspective that should be scrutinized and strictly connected to the quality of
institutions and investments for human capital accumulation.
The rest of the paper is structured as follows. In Section 2 we specifically analyze the
RCH while in Section 3 we underline the effects of institutions and measures of human
well-being on the RCH. In Section 4 we describe the classic EKC contributions and we
build a partially modified EKC that accounts for human development and sustainability.
In Section 5 we test the possibility of building an integrated model linking the RCH with
the modified EKC, which allows us to analyze the reciprocal causality links among
economic growth, human development and sustainability with special attention given to
the role of the globalization process and the quality of institutions. Section 6 concludes
with some reflections on the policy actions proposed at international level.
2. THE RESOURCE CURSE HYPOTHESIS: THEORIES
The Resource Curse Hypothesis maintains that countries with high natural resources
endowments have experienced lower economic growth rates than countries with scarce
stocks of natural resources. The resource curse is paradoxical because production of
natural resources has been the initial source of nearly all development, providing an
3
almost immediate source of foreign exchange, attracting foreign capital and skills and
increasing the availability of both raw materials for processing and a market for
manufactured inputs. Nonetheless, over the last fifty years, countries rich in natural
(commercial) resources (e.g., Russia, Nigeria and Venezuela) experienced economic
growth that was somewhat lower than other countries with scarce resources (Auty,
2001).
Sachs and Warner (1995) provided a first formulation of an empirical RCH, claiming
that the resource curse is a historically common pattern and the abundance of natural
resources is one of the most evident causes of low economic performances. Countries
that base their economies on natural resources tend to be examples of development
failures. In contrast, countries such as Japan, Hong Kong, Korea and Ireland
experienced high economic growth rates although they had relatively lower endowments
of natural resources. A third category includes countries with a relatively higher
dependence on primary resources and good growth performance as is the case for
Norway and Botswana.
One of the first explanations for the observed slow growth rate despite the resource
endowments in some countries has been attributed to the substantial terms of trade
volatility in primary commodity exports (Mikesell, 1997).3 Empirical investigations have
not been able to find a strong relationship between terms of trade volatility and per
capita growth (Sachs and Warner, 1999; Sala-i-Martin et al., 2003), and have turned to
other transmission channels in order to explain such a curse. The main body of literature
suggests five different explanations: the Dutch disease effect, the misallocation of
revenues from resource exploitation, the rent seeking behavior, the quality of institutions
and the role of human capital (Auty, 2001; Ross, 1999).
The Dutch disease hypothesis suggests that a resource boom will divert a country’s
resources away from activities that are more conducive to long-term growth.4 A resource
boom causes the appreciation of the exchange rate, producing a contraction in
In this context, terms of trade volatility is defined as the standard deviation of the percentage growth
rate of the terms of trade.
4 The term ‘Dutch disease’ was used for the first time in relation to the discovery and importation of
silver in the 16th century to the Netherlands, and the related negative economic impacts occurred in the
country. Normally, the term refers to adverse effects on the traded sector when resources income pushes
domestic demand up and adverse effects on economic growth following the reallocation of production
factors (Matsen and Torvik, 2005).
3
4
manufacturing exports or displacement of capital and labor factors away from
manufacturing towards the extractive industries and raising manufacturing costs as a
result. Moreover, the appreciation of the exchange rate reduces prices for tradable
products (manufactured goods and agricultural products) relative to prices of nontradables (construction and services) so that labor and capital are withdrawn from the
tradable sector (considered typically the most dynamic one, with positive effects in terms
of economic growth) and flow into the non-tradable sector. Foreign Direct Investment
(FDI) may be attracted by investment opportunities in the export boom sector which
may cause further appreciation of the real exchange rate. The increased capital imports
may lower the interest rate which induces domestic capital to go abroad in response to
higher earnings.5 Obviously FDI inflows would have such negative impacts only in the
case of highly concentration in the resource-intensive sector. The movement of
resources between sectors may reduce capital accumulation. If the non-tradable sector is
relatively labor intensive while the tradable sector is more capital intensive, the
movement in favor of the non-tradable sector will tend to raise wages and lower returns
to capital, thereby reducing capital accumulation. Furthermore, technological progress is
faster in the traded sector than in the non-tradable sector. The more recent explanations
of the resource curse based on the Dutch disease effect include the role of Learning by
Doing (LD) differently distributed among the sectors. The agreement rests upon the
assumption that LD is only generated in the traded sector (implicitly assumed to be the
manufacturing sector). Since a foreign exchange gift (linked to competitive exports in the
international market) decreases the size of the traded sector through the reduction of
capital accumulation and investment in such activities, productivity growth is reduced
(i.e., the reduction of the tradable sector productivity is more than proportionate to the
reduction of investments whereas the increasing productivity in the non-tradable sector
is proportionate to the increasing factor endowment). When the real exchange rate
appreciation is accompanied by increasing real exchange rate volatility, the traded sector
is further depressed because investment is reduced (Torvik, 2001).
Theoretical and empirical models of Dutch disease have been developed by van
5 The negative effects of a Dutch disease hypothesis from the supply side could exceed the positive effects
on the demand side linked to a resource boom if the revenues from the resource exploitation are deeply
concentrated and the resulting increase in income per capita is far less then the increase in revenues. The
extractive activities are typically capital-intensive, and the resource boom would have a smooth effect in
terms of increasing real wages.
5
Wijinbergen (1984), Torvik (2001) and Matsen and Torvik (2005) among others. It must
be underlined that Dutch disease effects are mainly used for an explanation of negative
economic performance due to a temporary resources boom (in terms of both increasing
resource stocks or rising resource price). As in van Wijnbergen (1984), high but
temporary resource revenues may be a mixed blessing. Many oil producing developing
countries encountered serious problems in building up a diversified export base whereas
West European oil and gas producers (Netherlands and United Kingdom) suffered a
decline in their traded goods (manufacturing) sector induced by real wages pressures.
Directly linked to the Dutch disease effect, a second explanation is based on the role of
savings. Among resource-rich countries, empirical evidence has shown that those
countries with the highest (resource wealth adjusted) savings rate generally have
managed to escape the resource curse (Atkinson and Hamilton, 2003; Boyce and Emery,
2005; Neumayer, 2004). Countries that manage their resource wealth more in accordance
with the optimality criteria will fare better than those who do not. Looking at data on
resource wealth-adjusted savings rate – built on the basis of the World Bank Genuine
Savings measure (column GS in Table 1) - there is a propensity for countries that have
escaped the resource curse (Malaysia, Thailand, as only developing countries examples)
to have a higher resource wealth-adjusted savings rate than those that have not escaped
(Congo, Nigeria, United Arab Emirates, among others).6
The adjusted saving rates with consumption of natural resources are the very first signal
of a misallocation of revenues from exploitation of such resources. Negative values of
GS characterize countries with a resource curse whereas positive values of GS are
associated with virtuous countries. It should be noted that Oman (an oil dependent
country) has a positive (but low) economic growth rate but a deeply negative adjusted
saving. This means that income growth has been obtained through the dissipation of
natural capital without appropriate investments to replace the exhaustible resources.
From a sustainability point of view, such growth progress will not last forever because
capital accumulation is less than the amount that must be produced in the future
constant (or increasing) income flows.
Most of the time, the decision to invest revenue from resource exploitation or not is
The average value reported in table 1 is partially decreased by Oman with an outlying value (-112.89) but
compensated by the Japanese resource wealth adjusted savings (+137.6). Notes on Genuine Savings
methodology are addressed in par. 4.
6
6
biased by distorted price signals. If the market price of the resource does not include all
the factors affecting the real total production cost (as the sum of the marginal extraction
cost plus the marginal use cost), the resource will seem more profitable (with a higher
marginal profit) and it will be exploited at an unsustainable rate. The effective
consumption path will be higher than the constant consumption path whereas the reinvestment of resource revenues will be less than the amount required to replace the
resource depletion. This overexploitation will negatively affect the long-term economic
growth (Atkinson and Hamilton, 2003).7
Alternative economic measures of resources depletion such as the El Serafy method proposed by
Neumayer (2004), have been taken into account by Atkinson and Hamilton (2003) but for the chosen time
period (and with low discount rates such as those used by the World Bank), the estimates would not be
highly divergent.
7
7
Table 1 – Main statistics for countries: resource curse and resource blessing
Resource curse
Bolivia
Central African Rep.
Congo, Dem. Rep.
Jamaica
Kuwait
Mauritania
Nicaragua
Nigeria
Peru
Saudi Arabia
Senegal
United Arab Emirates
Venezuela
Average
Resource blessing
Chile
Hong Kong
Indonesia
Ireland
Japan
Korea, Rep.
Malaysia
Norway
Oman
Sri Lanka
Syrian Arab Republic
Thailand
Tunisia
Average
EG
1970-2003
0.21
-1.23
-3.94
-0.16
-2.87
0.34
-1.73
0.12
0.09
0.41
0.16
-3.23
-1.42
-1.02
GS
1970-2003
-2.33
-2.79
-6.57
0.25
-47.05
-45.87
3.70
-18.80
9.51
-85.46
-6.43
-2.52
-8.23
-16.35
EG
1970-2003
2.52
4.30
3.82
4.01
2.40
5.47
3.79
2.83
1.99
2.89
2.15
4.24
2.89
3.33
GS
1970-2003
-8.99
81.02
9.70
40.20
137.60
35.79
17.38
31.00
-112.89
19.00
-3.16
39.64
13.51
23.06
DIFFUSE
POINT
TOT-RES
LIFE 1970
EDU 1970
IQ 2004
HDI 2003
1.85
10.29
3.93
5.81
0.57
4.54
20.11
4.16
4.94
0.07
12.45
0.61
0.36
5.36
19.29
0.03
17.20
5.54
68.45
35.53
0.66
20.84
5.28
67.62
4.48
41.84
24.98
23.98
21.14
10.31
21.13
11.35
69.02
40.07
20.78
24.99
10.22
67.70
16.93
42.45
25.34
29.34
46.07
42.36
45.16
68.36
66.11
42.64
53.89
42.86
53.94
52.31
40.86
61.11
65.12
52.37
24.56
4.18
9.39
45.56
63.45
2.13
17.22
5.24
30.67
12.05
9.29
21.83
34.96
21.58
-0.43
-1.39
-1.70
-0.05
0.30
-0.21
-0.32
-1.21
-0.35
-0.38
-0.18
0.69
-0.97
-0.48
0.69
0.36
0.39
0.74
0.84
0.48
0.69
0.45
0.76
0.77
0.46
0.85
0.77
0.63
DIFFUSE
POINT
TOT_RES
LIFE 1970
EDU 1970
GOV 2004
HDI 2003
1.23
1.52
8.06
14.72
0.41
2.60
23.97
3.84
0.11
13.16
3.23
10.51
6.17
6.89
9.99
0.64
11.95
1.68
0.16
0.78
9.82
4.79
49.77
0.65
7.76
1.68
8.61
8.33
11.22
2.16
20.01
16.40
0.58
3.39
33.78
8.63
49.88
13.81
10.99
12.18
14.78
15.22
62.40
69.96
47.92
71.09
71.95
59.93
61.55
74.19
47.37
64.65
55.79
58.44
54.19
61.49
37.40
35.81
16.09
73.76
86.59
41.61
34.23
83.49
0.00
47.00
38.09
17.42
22.69
41.09
1.25
1.31
-0.74
1.48
1.13
0.61
0.38
1.74
0.49
-0.25
-0.91
0.03
-0.01
0.50
0.85
0.92
0.70
0.95
0.94
0.90
0.80
0.96
0.78
0.75
0.72
0.78
0.75
0.83
HDI
1975-2003
0.36
0.02
-0.05
0.16
0.34
0.21
0.25
0.20
0.33
0.43
0.21
0.43
0.19
0.24
HDI
1975-2003
0.51
0.65
0.43
0.71
0.60
0.66
0.47
0.72
0.57
0.37
0.39
0.42
0.49
0.54
The exact definition of all variables is available in Table A1 in the Appendix. All data are from World Development
Indicators, data base 2004, The World Bank.
8
The third explanation of the RCH is linked to the presence of rent seeking behavior,
based on the assumption that resource rents are easily appropriable and this, in turn,
leads to distortion in public policies and pressure from lobbies and oligopolistic
companies to seek public favors (Torvik, 2002). Concentration of rents in the hands of a
few private owners directs revenue away from human resources, infrastructures,
traditional agriculture, small enterprise towards consumption and rent dissipation.
Rent seeking behavior negatively affects economic growth under three specific
conditions (Baland and Francois, 2000).8 First, entrepreneurial activity, by creating new
and better goods and services, destroys rents accruing to those holding licenses
restricting trade in already existing goods and services. Secondly, profits to entrepreneurs
increase with aggregate income. Thirdly, rent-seekers possess entrepreneurial skills and
can switch between these activities. Under these conditions, an increase in
entrepreneurship reduces rent-seeking and encourages further entrepreneurship. On the
contrary, a resource boom provides increasing revenues for rent-seekers, and
entrepreneurship (and economic growth) will be reduced.
Similar mechanisms are explained in Torvik (2002) with a specific model explaining that
in the event of a resource boom, rent-seeking activities become more profitable then
before whereas modern production sector guarantees the same level of profits. In this
case, rent-seeking activities become more attractive and entrepreneurs from modern
sectors move to rent-seeking activities. Under the hypothesis that modern sector has
increasing returns to scale whereas rent-seeking activities have constant returns to scale,
a reduction in the modern activities produces a fall in production that is greater than the
increase in the production of rent-seeking activities, thus reducing total output and
therefore welfare. Furthermore, the timing of the natural resource boom is important as
is the sectoral distribution of the increasing returns and whether the boom stimulates the
right sectors. Following Sachs and Warner (1999), conditions such as the degree of trade
openness and the structural dimension of the economic system (development stage, as
There are different forms of rent seeking (Bhagwati, 1982): premium seeking, or activities whereby
claimants compete for premium-fetching import licenses; revenue seeking, where economic agents try to
obtain a slice of the tariff revenue resulting from the adoption of a protectionist tariff and tariff seeking,
where lobbies seek protectionist trade tariffs. All these components lead to directly unproductive profit
seeking behavior. Such agents “yield pecuniary returns but do not produce goods or services that enter a
utility function directly or indirectly via increased production or availability to the economy of goods that
enter a utility function” (Bhagwati, 1982, p. 989).
8
9
primary sector led economies vs. tertiary sector) seem to be specific conditions that
affect the natural resource curse.
A fourth explanation looks deeply at the relationships between the quality of institutions
and the capacity to manage resources exploitation with theoretical (Mehlum et al., 2002;
2005) and empirical studies (Bulte et al., 2005; Isham et al., 2003; Leite and Weidmann,
1999; Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian, 2003). The linkages between the resource curse
and the role of institutions may be divided into two strands: where the quality of
institutions is damaged by resource abundance and constitutes the intermediate causal
link between resources and economic performance and where resources interact with the
quality of institutions so that resource abundance is a blessing when institutions are good
and a curse when institutions are bad. The first linkage (destruction of institutions or an
obstacle to the formation of solid institutions) can be found in many examples including
Saudi Arabia, Sudan, Nigeria, Angola and Congo, to mention a few. On the other hand,
natural resources endowment may not negatively affect institutional quality as in Chile,
Malaysia and Norway. It is worth noticing that countries with a higher quality of
institutions (except for Norway) are those with lesser resources endowments (e.g., Hong
Kong and Ireland).
Finally, a fifth explanation classifies recent contributions that have stressed the
importance of other characteristics, conjunctural and structural, linked to the absence of
adequate investments in enhancing human resources (Gylfason, 2001). In particular, a
contribution by Gylfason (2001) has emphasized that resource abundance may have the
effect of “crowding out” the accumulation of human capital, reducing the incentives for
investments in education or knowledge sectors (such explanation is partially linked to the
LD effect). As claimed by Atkinson and Hamilton (2003), public investments in human
capital accumulation makes a great contribution to economic growth in resource
abundant countries whereas countries with higher government consumption have
generally experienced a significant resource curse. This result is consistent with the
fourth explanation of the RCH based on the quality of institutions. Countries that
escaped from the curse present a higher initial level for dimensions such as life
expectancy at birth and secondary gross enrolment ratio. If we look at the average value
for all the variables in Table 1, it is clear that a relative abundance of natural resources,
10
especially fuels and minerals (defined as point resources)9 goes hand in hand with a lower
level of initial level of human development dimensions and with a lower growth rate of
human development index (HDI).
The last two explanations linked to the role of institutions and the investments in human
capital are more recent than the classic RCH. In particular, the role of corruption, rule of
law, government effectiveness and voice and accountability are analyzed by Isham et al.
(2003), Leite and Weidmann (1999) and Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian (2003) after the
considerable efforts of Kauffman et al. (2003) to provide widely accepted measures of
institutional quality. The specific role of education in the development process and the
effects of natural resources are empirically investigated in Bulte at al. (2005) and
Gylfason (2001) with special attention to investments in secondary education,
recognized as one of the most effective policy actions through which the resource curse
can be avoided (as shown for Botswana in Sarraf and Jinwanji, 2001). As in Papyrakis
and Gerlagh (2004), the schooling transmission channel is almost twice as important as
the corruption channel whereas the indirect effects of resource abundance on growth
through the institutional quality are higher than the direct effects on economic growth
(Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian, 2003).
These two transmission channels offer specific links between economic growth, natural
resources, human development and even globalization where institutional quality and
schooling are specific dimensions of the wider concept of human development and
capabilities approach.
In this context, globalization seems to operate in contrasting directions. Countries with a
larger share of natural resources on total exports may be negatively affected by
expanding export flows in primary products as the RCH occurs. On the contrary, the
main literature on economic growth has found consistent results of positive effects of
trade liberalization on the economic performance and development path (Dollar and
Kraay, 2003, 2004; Frankel and Romer, 1999).
Moreover, considering the financial flows that characterizes globalization, as FDI or
technological diffusion and royalties (Stiglitz, 2000; Winters, 2004), the relative
Recent studies adopted a distinction between natural resources classifying them as “diffuse” resources,
agriculture and food production and as “point” resources, fossil fuels and mineral production, recognizing
that this second type is the main responsible for the negative effects on economic growth (Bulte et al.,
2005; Isham et al., 2003).
9
11
abundance of natural resources could be a source of bias in the correct allocation of
financial and investment flows. Due to large initial investments necessary for the
exploitation of oil and mineral reserves, there is often no market competition and the
exploitation of resources is managed by a few oligopolistic firms that are often
controlled by foreign multinationals. The capital flows from resource exploitation could
be invested abroad and most of the revenues from national resource endowments lost.
The facility of capital investment on international markets could partially increase the
exit of such revenues.10
3. THE RESOURCE CURSE HYPOTHESIS AND THE ROLE OF
INSTITUTIONS
The general formulation for the RCH is represented in equation [1] where we distinguish
globalization (GLOB) as a specific aspect, other conditioning variables (COND)
representing other macroeconomic aspects, human development dimensions (HD) and
finally, natural resources endowments (NR) and the quality of institutions (INST):
EGt −T = β 0 + β1 ln GDPT + β 2GLOBt −T + β 3CONDt-T + β 4 HDT + β 5 NRT + β 6 INSTt + ei [1]
Initial GDP per capita is included in all the empirical studies on this issue, on the basis
of the idea of conditional convergence: an economy will enjoy a faster growth rate the
further it is from its own steady state value of output. EG performance and the income
per capita level reached at the end of the analyzed period are deeply influenced by some
conditioning variables which influence the savings rate, capital and labor productivity
(Barro and Sala-i-Martin, 1995). These conditioning variables include trade openness,
FDI flows, public investments in human capital accumulation, natural resources
endowments, quality of institutions and so on.
In our specification, globalization includes trade openness (defined following the
A counter example has been given by the last policy options chosen by the president Hugo Chavez in
Venezuela, where oil companies are now all dependent on national government and revenues from oil
exports are invested in infrastructures and human capital. In the Venezuelan case, the absence of
consolidated democratic institutions has been surely one of the main obstacles to a rapid and consistent
economic growth during last decades.
10
12
measure of trade openness provided by Sachs and Warner, 1995b), FDI flows and low
inflation rate as a proxy of macroeconomic stability on the international markets
(Winters, 2004) whereas other conditioning variables include private investments. HD
dimensions are represented as the initial level of life expectancy and secondary education
as a proxy for the initial level of human capital. Natural resources (NR) are estimated
separately as point and diffuse resources as described above. Moreover, the quality of
institutions (INST) is considered a specific conditioning variable because the variation
across societies of the institutions is a relevant condition to growth and development
paths such as the security of property rights, prevalence of corruption, structures of the
financial sector, or investments in infrastructures and social capital (Sokoloff and
Engerman, 2000). In particular, the role of the institutions in enhancing the broader
social capability has been highlighted as a major development engine (Abramovitz, 1986,
1993).
Other macroeconomic conditioning variables such as export price level or terms of trade
are not included in the analysis due to the recurrent non-significant statistics in previous
studies on the RCH (Neumayer, 2004; Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian, 2003).
Furthermore, what we are really interested in is the role of structural features such as the
level of well-being and sustainability rather than more conjunctural issues such as price
level fluctuations.
Results in Table 2 are consistent with those found in the RCH literature where NR
endowment negatively affects the EG performance and both diffuse and point resources
coefficients are statistically significant in each model specification.
With regard to the effects linked to the globalization process, from this first specification
it seems that trade openness has positive effects on EG whereas FDI does not
significantly affect EG, due to low coefficients with non-robust statistic tests. On the
contrary, the positive role of capital investments is consistent in all specifications.
The positive effects linked to INST and initial HD (especially life expectancy at birth)
are consistently high, in line with other specific results on the effects of health
conditions on economic growth (Bhargava et al., 2000). In particular, the role of
education as initial human capital endowments has the same role as the initial GDP level
where countries with higher school enrolment ratios are those with lower growth rates.
13
Table 2 – Model specification for the resource curse hypothesis
Dependent variable:
EG 1970-2003
Initial GDP
TRADE
FDI
INVESTMENTS
IQ
RL
GE
DIFFUSE
POINT
Initial LIFE EXPECT.
Initial SEC. EDU.
CONSTANT
Number of Observations
Adjusted R-squared
(1)
(2)
(3)
(4)
(5)
-0.864*
-0.780*
-1.124*
-1.124*
-1.102*
(-6.75)
(-6.40)
(-6.53)
(-6.95)
(-7.17)
1.240*
1.191*
1.366*
1.172*
1.115*
(3.03)
(3.10)
(3.55)
(3.14)
(3.12)
0.037
0.101
0.033
0.066
0.047
(0.37)
(0.87)
(0.29)
(0.63)
(0.46)
3.784*
3.961*
3.201*
3.115*
3.001*
(7.61)
(8.51)
(6.21)
(6.32)
(6.30)
1.160*
0.917*
0.959*
..
..
(4.92)
(4.02)
(4.24)
..
..
..
..
..
1.031*
..
..
..
..
(5.27)
..
..
..
..
..
1.133*
..
..
..
..
(6.02)
..
-3.689*
-3.459*
-3.121**
-2.581**
..
(-2.14)
(-2.07)
(-1.95)
(-1.67)
..
-3.174*
-2.423*
-2.502*
-2.625*
..
(-3.86)
(-2.87)
(-3.14)
(-3.44)
..
..
5.532*
5.723*
5.276*
..
..
(3.66)
(3.96)
(3.81)
..
..
-1.568
-1.937*
-1.984*
..
..
(-1.65)
(-2.11)
(-2.26)
13.157*
13.624*
12.203*
12.328*
12.035*
(10.77)
(11.46)
(9.90)
(10.49)
(10.72)
95
0.65
94
0.71
90
0.75
90
0.77
90
0.79
Statistics for t-Student in parenthesis. * p-values < 0.05, ** p-values < 0.1.
In order to quantify the real effect linked to the quality of institutions, most of the recent
contributions consider this aspect endogenous. In this analysis, the general formulation
of the institution-related equation (INST) has been structured in the same way as in
previous contributions and takes into account the specific role of globalization, human
development dimensions and natural resources:
INSTt = β 0 + β1 ln GDPT + β 2 GLOBt −T + β 3CONDt −T + β 4 HDT + β 5 HDt −T + β 6 NRT + ei
[2]
14
where GLOB and NR variables are exactly the same as those tested for eq. [1] whereas
other conditioning variables include not only the initial level of HD but also changes that
have occurred during the analyzed period (t-T).
In order to increase the robustness of the estimates, most of the authors apply a two
stage system of equation (2SLS) with a specific formulation for growth and links with
natural resources consumption on one side and another equation with formal
relationships between the quality of institutions and the relative abundance of resources
(Bulte et al., 2005; Isham et al., 2003; Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian, 2003).11
It is worth noticing that globalization (trade openness and FDI) only positively affect the
quality of institutions but the direct influence on EG has been reduced. High levels of
investments remain positively correlated with EG and a low inflation rate contributes to
the quality of institutions. This last result is particularly interesting and explains the role
of macroeconomic stability in promoting good institutions (Table 3).
When a 2SLS model is applied, the effects of initial level of HD on EG partially change.
The coefficient associated with life expectancy at birth increases in RCH equation
whereas it is not significant for INST equation. If we consider the secondary school
enrolment ratio, it is worth noticing that the negative direct effect on EG (reclaiming the
same mechanism for initial GDP level) is partially compensated by the positive indirect
effect linked to INST. This result indicates the important role of human capital
endowments (and accumulation) in guaranteeing a high quality of the institutions. The
relatively low coefficient associated with changes in HD dimensions (human capital
accumulation) highlights the major role played by initial conditions.
Following Boschini et al. (2005), we tested whether there is endogeneity between income growth and
institutions through the resource intensity channel, and the Hausman test confirms this hypothesis, with pvalues associated to a joint-F test lower than 5%. Endogeneity could create biased estimations if the model
errors are correlated with the dependent variable. One approach used to test for endogeneity is a
procedure known as Hausman test. The basic idea is to test the null hypothesis that endogeneity between
the instrument variables and the endogenous variables have no significant impact on the estimates. The
null hypothesis is accepted if the two estimates of the same equation differ only randomly. First, we ran
the two-stage least square (2SLS) regression, and, after an additional OLS regression, we calculated the
Hausman test to analyze if the 2SLS and OLS results are significantly different. The Hausman test with a
p-value of 0.05 indicates that the null hypothesis, that differences in coefficients are not systematic, can be
rejected and hence the OLS regression is not a consistent and efficient estimator.
11
15
Table 3 –Resource curse hypothesis and quality of institutions
Variable
Initial GDP
TRADE
FDI
RCH(1)
-0.856*
INST(1)
0.233*
RCH(2)
-0.741*
INST(2)
0.230*
RCH(3)
-1.230*
INST(3)
0.191*
(-3.82)
(2.73)
(-3.50)
(2.61)
(-6.31)
(2.29)
0.410*
0.944
1.103**
0.817
(1.44)
(1.83)
(1.60)
(2.06)
0.077
0.153
0.013
0.116*
(0.72)
(1.23)
(0.11)
(2.13)
INFLATION
-0.249*
(-3.30)
INVESTMENTS
3.753*
(6.50)
RL
1.167*
3.895*
(1.99)
Initial LIFE EXPECT.
Initial SEC. EDU.
2.957*
0.130
(7.24)
(5.56)
(0.49)
0.821*
1.500*
(1.48)
(3.09)
..
0.002
-0.323
6.028*
..
(0.00)
(-0.39)
(3.96)
(0.12)
..
2.125*
2.276*
-2.537*
1.487*
(-2.30)
..
-0.103
(3.86)
(4.15)
Change LIFE EXPECT.
0.031
-0.012
(0.15)
(-0.06)
(-0.15)
Change SEC. EDU.
0.028*
0.035*
0.024*
(2.70)
(3.24)
(2.45)
DIFFUSE
POINT
CONSTANT
Number of Observations
Adjusted R-squared
(2.91)
-0.026
..
-3.554*
-0.470
-2.728
..
(-2.04)
(-0.53)
(-1.61)
-0.974
(-1.16)
..
-3.347*
-0.876*
-2.213*
-0.742*
..
(-3.58)
(-1.78)
(-2.55)
(-1.72)
13.368*
-2.585*
13.538*
-2.361*
12.758*
-0.703
(8.79)
(-5.71)
(9.56)
(-4.92)
(9.95)
(-1.10)
91
0.67
91
0.75
90
0.72
90
0.76
90
0.75
90
0.83
Statistics for t-Student in parenthesis. * p-values < 0.05, ** p-values < 0.1.
Finally, with regard to NR it is clear that the direct effect found in the single equation
model becomes non-robust for diffuse resources whereas for point resources it is still
consistent both for EG and INST equations. In particular, the indirect effect channeled
through the role of institutions is statistically consistent and higher than the direct one. If
we calculate the direct effect of NR on the quality of institutions as the product of the
coefficient associated with POINT in INST(3) (-0.742) with the standard deviation of
16
POINT (+16.59) and we multiply then such a result by the coefficient of INST (+1.500
in RCH(3)), we obtain the indirect effect of NR channeled by institutions (-18.47) which
corresponds to a decrease in EG of 0.54% per year in addition to the average annual
reduction of about 1% directly associated with the RCH mechanism.
Following the explanation based on institutional quality, the presence of point resources
seems to have a greater effect on the growth path than the presence of diffuse resources
(Isham et al., 2003). The presence of large oil or mineral reserves is one of the major
causes of corruption and misallocation of rents from resource exploitation. Therefore,
natural resource abundance is negative for economic development especially if the
country lacks proper institutions for dealing with conflicts and corruption (Boschini et
al., 2003). This result reaffirms the important role played by the corruption of
institutions induced by resource abundance (Leite and Weidmann, 1999).
Following Bulte et al. (2005), Isham et al. (2003) and Sala-i-Martin and Subramanian
(2003), Rule of Law (RL) and Government Effectiveness (GE) seem to be more
consistent with other control variables for economic growth modeled with natural
resources abundance and human development dimensions. At the same time, these two
dimensions have absolute magnitudes of the effects of the natural resource variables that
are higher than the other variables for institutions available.12 In general, model
specification using RL as an institutional quality proxy fits very well with our hypothesis
whereas, when using the GE variable, the equation for institutions has inconsistent
estimates for globalization variable and natural resources. Furthermore, eq. [2] calculated
with GE gives heteroskedasticity and requires a GLS estimator.
In this context, we have not adopted all the control variables for institutions indicated in
the main literature and we have ignored variables such as ethnic fractionalization, the
fraction of people speaking English as a first language or the fraction of people speaking
a European language, as in the other papers linking the RCH with institutions. This is
for two reasons. First, these variables are not updated to 2002 and they are only available
for 1998. Secondly, some of these control variables could help to explain the
relationships between growth and consumption of natural resources but they are not of
12
Our results are consistent with results in other papers where natural resource abundance is
analyzed together with institutional quality. Such measures are based on indicators provided in
Kaufmann et al. (1999, 2003) where six different characteristics describe the quality of institutions:
Rule of Law (RL), Political Instability (PI), Government Effectiveness (GE), Control of Corruption
(CC), Regulatory Framework (RF), and Property Rights and Rule-based Governance (PR).
17
fundamental importance and they are sometimes not statistically significant.
Furthermore, as in Isham et al. (2003), the effects linked to variables such as a country’s
share of English and European language speakers are less than the effects of natural
resources endowment on economic growth and institutions. In Bulte et al. (2005), these
variables are not statistically significant whereas basic human development dimensions
are much more influential.
The results in this section show that point resources affect national institutions.
Secondly, institutions that are endogenously determined by the nature of natural
resource dependence (high share of primary exports on total exports or on GDP) are
significant (negative) determinants of growth.
4. THE ENVIRONMENTAL KUZNETS CURVE AND SUSTAINABILITY
The analysis based on the RCH described in the previous section represents a specific
point of view that models economic growth without specific consideration for
sustainability of development. In this sense, Neumayer (2004) has changed the
dependent variable in the growth equation, substituting traditional income per capita
with a measure of macroeconomic sustainability such as the Genuine Saving (GS) index
provided by the World Bank (2004). Moreover, links between economic growth and
sustainability under the RCH have been considered in Atkinson & Hamilton (2003)
where the achievement of a sustainable development path seems to be highly correlated
with the investments in human capital formation and consequently the human
development level.
In this context, the aim of this paper is to provide a link between the RCH modified
with the role of institutions on one side and the relationship between economic growth
and sustainable development on the other . In order to compare these two models, we
have adopted the so-called Environmental Kuznets Curve (EKC) formulation13 where
relationships between economic growth and pollution are synthesized. The classical
reduced functional form representing the EKC is given by equation [3]:
13 The exact term Environmental Kuznets Curve was introduced for the first time in Selden and Song
(1994).
18
E i = β 0 + β1 X i + β 2 X i2 + β 3 X i3 + β 4 COND i + e i
[3]
where Ei represents the general level of environmental stress and Xi the income per
capita. The inverted U-shaped curve deriving from such a formula requires β1 to be
positive, β2 negative and β3 positive.14
Two main arguments have been proposed to explain the EKC. On the demand side,
there is the role of public opinion in requiring policy actions to reduce environmental
degradation where environment is no more a luxury good, as it is in poor economies and
on the supply side, the role of structural changes in the economic system where
economic growth is followed by technological innovation and change in the productive
structure (from basic industries to high-tech services) producing a reduction in polluting
emissions (Barbier, 2003). The specific nature of the abatement technologies with
increasing returns to scale could constitute a further explanation of the EKC where high
fixed initial investment costs for pollution abating techniques reduce the capacity of
poor countries to implement pollution control policies (Andreoni & Levinson, 2001).
Many contributions have empirically tested the existence of an EKC using cross-country
relationships (Grossman & Krueger, 1995; Shafik, 1994; Stern et al., 1996) or time series
analyses (Egli, 2002; Vincent, 1997). Further contributions have introduced other control
variables in order to improve representation of the effects linked to trade openness,
globalization and the manufacturing sector (Cole, 2004; Hettige et al., 1998; Tisdell, 2001)
or linked to well-being aspects such as income distribution, education and health
(Gangadharan & Valenzuela, 2001; Hill & Magnani, 2002; Magnani, 2000). Finally, many
contributions try to shed some light on possible failures in the theoretical interpretation
of the EKC (Arrow et al., 1995; Munasinghe, 1999; Stern & Common, 2001).
In this context, we attempt to substitute the income factor of the EKC with a more
capability-oriented measure such as HD maintaining the other control variables such as
the percentage of polluting industries in the whole economy or the effect of
globalization on pollution. Furthermore, in order to represent a more general framework
geared towards sustainable development, the pure pollution dependent variable is
replaced by a macroeconomic sustainable indicator such as the negative value of GS.
The cubic term derives from the empirical evidence found by Grossman and Krueger (1995), where the
relationship between income and emissions becomes positive again for certain types of pollution (SOX) for
higher income level.
14
19
The GS index provided by the World Development Report is formally expressed in
equation [4]:
GS = K& − ( FR − f R )( R − g ) − b(e − d )
[4]
where K& represents economic capital formation while other terms are adjustments for
consumption and degradation of natural capital. In particular, the economic value of
natural resources consumption (resources extracted R minus natural growth rate g for
renewables) is given by the resource rental rate (FR) net of the marginal cost of extraction
(fR), while pollution (emissions e minus natural dissipation rate d) is evaluated by the
marginal cost of abatement b.
Separate economic values for some types of natural resources exploited at national level
such as energy and mineral resources, forests and marginal economic damage linked to
CO2 emissions (i.e., the cost of climate change) are then available.15
GS is based on the assumption of perfect resource substitutability and it could therefore
be interpreted as a limit value of sustainability, where
GS > 0
GS = 0
GS < 0
sustainability
minimum level of sustainability
non-sustainability
The inverted U-shaped relation between GDP per capita and pollutant emissions depicted in the EKC - can be re-formulated by using a modified EKC (MEKC),
replacing the GDP per capita with a modified Human Development Index (HDIM) that
does not include the income factor and replacing the pollution emissions with the
negative value of Genuine Saving per capita (-GS) as a measure of non-sustainability.
This simple accounting rule allows the original EKC - where the dependent variable is a
negative effect related to economic growth – to be compared with the MEKC.
Furthermore, the absence of the GDP index in the HDIM eliminates multicollinearity
between the GS and the HDI. The value added of such analysis is the presence of
Energy and mineral resources considered in the WDR are oil, natural gas, coal, bauxite, copper, lead,
iron, nickel, phosphates, tin, zinc, gold, silver. For methodological and empirical explanation of effective
components of Genuine Saving index, see Hamilton and Clemens (1999).
15
20
depletion and degradation value of natural resources contained in the GS index
compared with the simple pollutant emissions considered in a classical EKC model
(Costantini, 2006). In addition, using a HD measure and not a simple EG level allows
broader considerations to be made on the sustainability of the development path or if
future generations could enjoy the same well-being level (and not only income). In line
with classic EKC, the inclusion of other control variables such as trade flows and
manufactures as the share of value added even allows us to analyze the effects of
economic globalization on sustainable development.
The estimation output (Table 4) comes from a GLS specification in order to correct the
heteroskedasticity of the error terms as underlined in a number of contributions (Cole,
2004; Egli, 2002; Gangadharan & Valenzuela, 2001; Hill & Magnani, 2002). Traditional
EKC estimates are similar to the results available in the literature and are consistent for
the three years considered (1990, 1995, 2000). The cubic term in EKC3 (2000) is
significant but the R-squared is reduced (examples of EKC applied to CO2 emissions use
both quadratic and cubic model specifications). Accounting for other control variables,
such as trade (as % of GDP) and manufacture value added (as % of GDP), or human
development (expressed as a HDIM excluding the income term), improve the estimates.
In particular, a higher value of trade and manufacture are associated with higher CO2
emissions, isolating the composition effect and the scale effect claimed for a supply-side
explanation of the EKC. This is consistent with Chichinilsky (1994) and Suri and
Chapman (1998) where increasing openness to trade is associated with increasing
pollution emissions especially for developing countries due to the delocalization of
polluting industries known as the pollution heaven effect (Copeland and Taylor, 2004).
Estimates of a MEKC that account for human development and sustainability give
results that are quite similar to traditional EKC, with lower values of R-squared but
statistically significant parameters (excluding the hypothesis of a cubic term that gives
estimates that are not always consistent).
In particular, considering the quality of institutions expressed as Rule of Law (RL), the
R-squared is consistently higher, once again stressing the role of institutions as an engine
for economic growth and sustainable development. It is worth noting that in the case of
the MEKC, the three conditioning variables (trade, manufacture and institutions)
positively contribute to reaching a higher level of GS (but manufacture is not statistically
significant), as an opposite result of the traditional EKC.
21
Table 4 –Traditional and modified Environmental Kuznets Curve
Panel A: (CO2)
GDP
GDP^2
EKC1(2000)
EKC2(2000)
EKC3(2000)
EKC(1995)
EKC(1990)
2.875*
2.551*
5.059*
2.263*
2.187*
(21.40)
(19.33)
(5.45)
(17.38)
(11.04)
-0.133*
-0.120*
-0.472*
-0.108*
-0.090*
(-15.57)
(-16.20)
(-4.00)
(-13.76)
(-8.29)
GDP^3
0.016*
(3.17)
TRADE
MANUF.
0.278*
0.303*
0.287*
0.239*
0.156*
(6.43)
(7.69)
(8.47)
(6.11)
(3.75)
0.193*
0.073*
0.060*
0.150*
0.036
(6.44)
(2.75)
(2.14)
(3.83)
(0.44)
1.202*
1.947*
2.898*
1.227*
(5.65)
(8.34)
(14.25)
(3.18)
-7.068*
-6.250*
-12.061*
-6.818*
-5.656*
(-13.93)
(-2.88)
(-5.01)
(-15.20)
(-8.61)
141
0.73
138
0.80
138
0.76
124
0.81
98
0.78
MEKC1(2000)
MEKC2(2000)
MEKC3(2000)
MEKC(1995)
MEKC(1990)
2.784*
2.110*
-1.251
2.843*
2.483*
(7.58)
(7.35)
(-1.04)
(10.99)
(11.58)
-2.412*
-1.678*
4.002*
-2.493*
-2.257*
(-8.52)
(-7.38)
(2.04)
(-11.84)
(-13.37)
HDIM
CONSTANT
Numb obs
R-squared
Panel B: (-GS)
HDIM
HDIM^2
HDIM^3
-2.993**
(-2.91)
TRADE
MANUF.
-0.080*
-0.042*
-0.063*
-0.044*
-0.015*
(-5.05)
(-3.10)
(-5.31)
(-3.57)
(-1.40)
-0.020
-0.006
-0.027*
-0.023
-0.108
(-1.47)
(-0.46)
(-2.01)
(-1.59)
(-6.44)
-0.142*
-0.161*
-0.095*
(-13.20)
(-16.42)
(-10.33)
-8.214*
-8.382*
-7.672*
-8.344*
-8.483*
(-68.18)
(-83.51)
(-30.86)
(-104.67)
(-109.12)
0.37
133
0.52
132
0.51
132
0.42
121
0.40
101
RL
CONSTANT
R-squared
Numb obs
Statistics for t-Student in parenthesis. * p-values < 0.05, ** p-values < 0.1.
22
5. INTEGRATED
MODEL
OF
ENVIRONMENT,
DEVELOPMENT AND ECONOMIC GROWTH
HUMAN
Since income per capita per se is a poor indicator of welfare, rather than replacing
alternative developing indicators in the RCH equation as suggested in Bulte et al. (2005),
we attempt to introduce the well-being level in a MEKC function, estimating an
integrated model in order to account for a RCH - including the role on institutions - and
a MEKC, at current time t comparing to initial period T (omitting the i symbol for
countries).
The full model specification is:
− GS t = β 0 + β1 HDIM t + β 2 HDIM t2 + β3 HDIM t3 + β 4 CONDt + ei
[5]
EGt −T = β 0 + β1 ln GDPT + β 2 GLOBt −T + β 3 CONDt -T + β 4 HDT + β 5 NRT + β 6 INSTt + ei
[6]
INSTt = β 0 + β1 ln GDPT + β 2 GLOBt −T + β 3CONDt −T + β 4 HDT + β 5 HDt −T + β 6 NRT + ei
[7]
HDIM t = β 0 + β1 ln GDPt + β 2 CONDt + β3CONDT + ei
[8]
ln GDPt = β 0 + β1 ( EGt −T ) * (t − T ) + β 2 ln GDPT + ei
[9]
where eq. [5] represents the MEKC, eq. [6] the RCH, and eq. [7] the role of endogenous
institutions. Finally, eq. [8] and [9] are introduced in order to capture both chain A and
chain B of the EG-HD relationships, as claimed in Boozer et al. (2003) and Ranis et al.
(2000). The simple formulation of chain A, where only a few determinants of HD that
are different from EG are included (initial level of GDP, initial level of life expectancy at
birth, CONDt, and other conditioning variables describing the actual situation,
CONDT), is due to represent the transmission channels in the RCH and the EKC in the
simplest way.
As in Isham et al. (2003), we have adopted a 3-stage least squares (3SLS) method of
estimation, since the model specification has both heteroskedasticity of error terms (for
the MEKC) and endogeneity. The results are consistent with estimations by Sala-i-
23
Martin & Subramanian (2003) where major transmission channels of the resource curse
to growth stagnation are linked to institutional quality and not directly to economic
growth.
Results in Table 5 represent estimates that both use only equations [5], [6], and [7] –
models (1) and (2) – and use the complete model (including equations [8] and [9]) –
model (3) - in order to account for the effects underlined by chain A. Results are quite
similar, and the inclusion of the two additional equations does not affect the robustness
of the estimates both for RCH and MEKC.16 The specific value added of such a
complete model is that it allows calculation of the value of HDIM corresponding to the
maximum non-sustainable GS level, and can therefore be compared with the GDP value
corresponding to the maximum CO2 emission level (given by the classic EKC).17
If we compare results of EKC with the turning point value of the MEKC, it is worth
noticing that the HD threshold level of the inverted U-shaped curve is around 0.60
where it is clearly a medium development level (that is perfectly consistent with the
average HDI value reported in Table 1 for countries in which the resource curse
occurred). Using chain A (eq. [8]), it is possible to calculate the HD level corresponding
to the GDP per capita that maximizes the CO2 emissions in the EKC (results not
reported in the paper). The turning point of the traditional EKC is around 30.000 US$
per capita – and this is consistent with most of the available contributions corresponding to around 0.95 HD using equation [8]. These first results confirm the
main criticisms of the EKC, related especially to the possibility of a different EG path - a
turning point well below the predicted ones from classic EKC for developing countries
as claimed by Munasinghe (1999) - which could invert the negative environmental effects
caused by the development process well before what has occurred in the past for
16 The robustness of the estimates reported in Table 5 has been tested by the insertion of regional
dummies and by reproducing the same system without Sub-Saharan African countries. In order to exclude
influence from outliers in the sample, we have applied Sachs and Warner (1995) criterion based on DFITS,
where DFITS is defined as the square root of [hi/(1-hi)], with hi representing an observation’s leverage,
multiplied by its studentized residual. An outlier is an observation with a DFITS that is greater in absolute
terms than twice the square root of (k/n), where k is the number of independent variables (including the
constant) and n the number of observations. Applying this criterion, the same model has been tested
excluding Botswana, Gabon, Malaysia and Zambia. The results remain coherent and consistent.
17 Estimates from two separate equations systems (not reported in the paper), the first one with the RCH
specification linked to institutional quality, and the second one with the simultaneous EKC, MEKC and
the HD (chain A) equation give quite similar results as the complete 3SLS, both for the statistical and
economic significance of regressors.
24
developed countries.
More generally, results provided by this model specification are not so distant from
results obtained from independent estimates of the RCH and EKC. The role of
globalization is positive in the sense that circulation of capital, people and technologies
has a positive impact on the sustainable management of natural resources. Such a
positive role is mainly linked to the positive role of institutions while trade openness and
FDI flows seem to have limited effects on EG (with non-robust estimates). On the
contrary, the role of HD dimensions is quite clear and unanimous where a higher initial
level of HD corresponds to positive effects on institutional quality and indirectly on EG.
With regard to sustainability, increasing HD is first associated with increasing
exploitation of natural resources until a threshold level where such relation becomes
positive and an increase in HD positively affects sustainability.
An increase in EG and in HD is associated with growing resource consumption in the
first stages of development where the industrialization process requires great efforts
from primary industries in the first development stage and the development of heavy
(polluting) industries in the second stage. If the EG and HD process is followed by
sufficient human capital accumulation with better institutions and qualified human
resources, the industrialization process will move towards a further development stage
characterized by the major role of services while reducing pollution and using less
natural resources. A virtuous circle of this kind could be reinforced by public
investments for health and education and more widely for social capability. The role of
skilled labor force in conjunction with a higher income level are all necessary conditions
for the adoption of an environmentally- friendly consumption path and production
techniques.
Finally, we maintain that natural resource endowment could be a source of low economic
growth rates if the institutions in a country do not have the ability to manage the resources
in the right way. Therefore, investment policies geared towards human capital formation
(education and high skilled labor forces) are to be considered the most effective actions for
reaching a higher development level. At the same time, during the first stages of the
development process, a large consumption of natural resources without appropriate
investment policies to replace depleted resources - as explained by the Hartwick rule, or
the investment of the Hotelling rent coming from the exploitation of natural resources could produce a development path that is not sustainable in the long run.
25
Table 5 – Model for RCH, INST, and MEKC (estimates for period 1970-2003)
Variables
RCH(1)
INST(1)
Initial GDP
-0.459*
(-2.11)
MEKC(1)
RCH(2)
INST(2)
0.260*
-1.054*
(2.91)
(-5.84)
1.008*
MEKC(2)
RCH(3)
INST(3)
0.152**
-1.115*
0.154*
0.004*
(1.74)
(-6.34)
(1.78)
(0.14)
0.421*
0.726
0.432*
OPENNESS
0.969
(1.42)
(1.93)
(2.03)
(1.46)
(2.10)
FDI
0.191
0.101
0.118*
0.050
0.116*
(1.40)
(0.80)
(2.02)
(0.41)
INFLATION
-0.259*
RL (2003)
-0.154
2.991*
-0.153
(7.33)
(5.85)
(-0.51)
(5.81)
(-0.51)
0.306
0.995*
Initial SEC. EDU.
Change LIFE EXPECT
Change SEC. EDU
POINT
(-3.47)
3.104*
(0.48)
DIFFUSE
(2.00)
4.163*
Initial LIFE EXPECT.
HDI(3)
-0.254*
(-3.50)
INVESTMENTS
MEKC(3)
1.404*
(2.00)
0.082*
(1.43)
-0.140*
(2.98)
(-13.15)
-0.721
5.527*
0.282
5.543*
0.267
(-0.87)
(3.66)
0.325
(3.80)
0.311
(6.45)
2.442*
-1.812
1.481*
-2.288*
1.487*
0.065
(4.06)
(-1.58)
(2.57)
(-2.08)
(2.91)
(0.85)
-0.051
-0.035
(-0.26)
(-0.20)
(-0.15)
0.149*
0.085*
0.024*
(1.98)
(1.13)
(2.45)
0.841*
-0.026
-4.364*
-0.240
-3.689*
-0.947
-3.371*
(-2.29)
(-0.26)
(-2.21)
(-1.11)
(-2.12)
-0.974
(-1.16)
-4.232*
-0.744*
-2.566*
-0.650**
-2.220*
-0.742*
(-3.28)
(-1.30)
(-2.32)
(-1.23)
(-2.11)
(-1.72)
GDP (2003)
-0.002
(-0.08)
HDIM (2003)
5.879*
5.652*
(4.62)
(4.59)
(5.21)
HDIM^2 (2003)
-4.691*
-4.541*
-4.977*
(-5.05)
(-5.03)
(-5.63)
TRADE (2003)
-0.076*
-0.087*
-0.091*
(-1.94)
(-2.22)
(-2.41)
MANUF. (2003)
0.001
0.005
0.009
(0.02)
CONSTANT
Numb. Obs
Adj Rsq
6.270*
(0.10)
(0.17)
12.242*
-2.611*
-10.039*
12.141*
-1.121*
-9.956*
12.418*
-1.153*
-10.153*
0.379*
(7.67)
(-5.00)
(-22.30)
(8.82)
(-1.39)
(-23.03)
(9.24)
(-1.44)
(-24.05)
(2.91)
70
0.67
70
0.70
70
0.40
70
0.75
70
0.79
70
0.40
70
0.74
70
0.79
70
0.52
70
0.86
Statistics for t-Student in parenthesis. * p-values < 0.05, ** p-values < 0.1.
26
6. CONCLUSIONS
Different causal linkages have been analyzed in economic growth, human development, and
environment and have provided some general results with regard to the sustainability of a
development process.
The first result is that – in line with the results of the EKC studies - achieving an adequate
sustainability level with a positive capital accumulation process is a very difficult task during the first
stage of development. The satisfaction of basic human needs is a necessary condition for such an
objective and environmental protection is considered a secondary (or luxury) good. Nevertheless,
applying a MEKC it seems that it is possible to reduce (and invert) an unsustainable growth path at a
medium level of development, while the reversing of environmental degradation using a traditional
EKC seems to occur in correspondence with high income levels.
The second result is that human capital accumulation represents an valuable means to reaching and
maintaining higher consumption path in the future. The positive role of health and education
achievements is much bigger than the negative effects linked to natural resources endowments. The
resource curse would not occur if appropriate investments in human capital accumulation have been
placed, producing consistent positive effects in terms of the quality of institutions. Better institutions
represent one of the most effective conditional variables for higher economic growth, together with
private capital investments. This last element is perfectly in line with conditional convergence of
Barro and Sala-i-Martin (1995), where higher savings rates are one of the variables which increase the
economic growth rate and the steady-state income level.
A third result concerns the specific role of globalization process. From our analysis there is no
specific sign that the globalization process could bring negative effects to developing countries. On
the contrary, according to Stiglitz (2002) trade openness and FDI inflows positively affect the quality
of institutions, and globalisation ceteris paribus could be a source of governance improvements for the
economies exposed to increasing trade and capital inflows. At the same time, countries need to know
how to invest the advantages they derive from such a process for the improvement of human
development, without wasting available (albeit scarce) resources. Developing countries positively
affected by the globalization process are those that succeed in modernizing their institutions in a
democratic manner, investing in infrastructures, ensuring macroeconomic stability, and above all
investing the relative benefits to enlarge people’s choices. At the same time, the sustainability of such
a process depends on how benefits from exploiting existing resources are invested and how depleted
resources are replaced.
Comparing results from RCH and MEKC, we may affirm that in order to convert the resource curse
into a blessing, it is necessary to increase investments in human capital accumulation and
consequently in the quality of institutions. At the very first stages of the development path, the
economic resources necessary to increase significantly human capital accumulation could be not
available. If this does occur, the negative impacts are twofold. An economy based on resources
exploitation without appropriate institutions would run into Dutch disease or rent-seeking effects,
with reduced EG and therefore low HD levels (following chain A). The excessive resource
27
exploitation at the beginning of the development path, associated with low investments in human
capital, would bring the country towards an unsustainable path, with negative GS values and low HD
levels.
In conclusion, developing countries should promote environmental protection as soon as possible
but industrialized countries could help this process through coordinated know-how and
technological transfer thus avoiding the great degradation and depletion of natural resources of the
past decades.
Achieving a higher standard of living and maintaining natural capital could be complementary goals
rather than competing ones by mutually reinforcing an upward spiral of development and economic
growth.
Our results confirm that human development should be the first objective of international
development policies whereas an increase in human well-being is necessary to provide a sustainability
path. Active participation of industrialized countries, following the general framework of the
Millennium Development Goals, is one of the necessary conditions for development. Globalization
process could be a source of great advantage even for developing countries, under the necessary
condition that they have adequate instruments to manage this process in a positive direction,
enhancing human capabilities with higher levels of health and education. A higher technological level
would transform such resource-intensive economies into knowledge-intensive ones reducing
depletion and degradation of natural resources and reinforcing the virtuous cycle of economic
growth and human development.
28
REFERENCES
Abramovitz, M., 1986. Catching up, forging ahead, and falling behind, Journal of Economic History Vol.
46, pp. 385-406.
Abramovitz, M., 1993, The Search for the Sources of Growth: Areas of Ignorance, Old and New,
Journal of Economic History Vol. 53 (2), pp. 217-43.
Acemoglu, D., Johnson, S., Robinson, J.A., 2001, The Colonial Origins of Comparative
Development: An Empirical Investigation, The American Economic Review Vol. 91 (5), pp. 13691401.
Anand, S., Sen A., 2000, Human Development and Economic Sustainability, World Development Vol.
28 (12), pp. 2029-2049.
Andreoni, J., Levinson, A., 2001, The simple analytics of the environmental Kuznets curve, Journal of
Public Economics n. 80, pp. 269-286.
Arrow, K., Bolin B., Costanza, R., et al., 1995, Economic growth, carrying capacity, and the
environment, Ecological Economics, n. 15, pp. 91-95.
Atkinson, G., Hamilton, K., 2003, Savings, Growth and the Resource Curse Hypothesis, World
Development, Vol. 31 (11), pp. 1797-1807.
Auty, R.M., 2001, The political economy of resource-driven growth, European Economic Review n.45,
pp. 839-846.
Baland, J-M., Francois, P., 2000, Rent-seeking and resource booms, Journal of Development Economics,
Vol. 61, pp. 527-542.
Barbier, E.B., 2003, The role of natural resources in economic development, Australian Economic
Paper, Vol. 42 (2), 2003, pp. 253-272.
Barro, R.J., Sala-i-Martin, X., 1995, Economic Growth, McGraw-Hill, New York.
Bhagwati J.N., 1982, Directly Unproductive, profit-Seeking (DUP) Activities, Journal of Political
Economy, Vol. 90 (5), pp. 988-1002.
Bhagwati J.N., 2004, In defense of globalization, Oxford University Press, New York.
Bhargava, A., Jamison, D.T., Lau, L., Murray, C.J.L., 2000, Modeling the Effects of Health on
Economic Growth, GPE Discussion Paper n . 33, Geneva, World Health Organization.
Boozer, M., Ranis G., Stewart F., Suri T., 2003, Paths to Success: The Relationship Between Human
Development and Economic Growth, Economic Growth Center Working Paper n. 874, Yale
University.
Boschini, a.D., Petterson, J., Roine, J., 2003, Resource curse or not: a question of appropriability,
Working Paper n. 534 Stockholm School of Economics.
Boyce, J.R., Emery, J.C.H., 2005, A Hotelling Explanation of “The Curse of Natural resources”,
Department of Economics Discussion Paper n. 06, University of Calgary, Alberta, Canada.
Bulte, E.H., Damania, R., Deacon, R.T., 2005, Resource Intensity, Institutions, and Development,
World Development, Vol. 33 (7), pp. 1029-1044.
Chichilnisky, G., 1994, North-South Trade and the Global Environment, American Economic Review
Vol. 84 (4), pp. 851-874.
Cole M.A., 2004, Trade, the pollution haven hypothesis and the environmental Kuznets curve:
examining the linkages, Ecological Economics, n. 48, pp. 71-81.
Copeland, B.R., Taylor, M.S., 2004, Trade, Growth and the Environment, Journal of Economic
Literature, Vol. 42 (1), pp. 7-71.
Costantini, V., 2006, Sustainable development and human development: an integrated approach,
Review of Political Economy (Italian version), forthcoming.
Dollar, D., Kray, A., 2003, Institutions, trade, and growth, Journal of Monetary Economics n. 50, pp.
133-162.
29
Dollar, D., Kray, A., 2004, Trade, growth, and poverty, The Economic Journal n. 114, pp. 22-49.
Egli H., 2002, Are Cross-Country Studies of the Environmental Kuznets Curve Misleading? New
Evidence from Time Series Data for Germany, Working Paper FEEM n 25.
Frankel, J.A., Romer, D., 1999, Does Trade Cause Growth?, The American Economic Review Vol. 89 (3),
pp. 379-399.
Fukuda-Parr, S. Shiva Kumar, A.K., 2003, Readings in Human Development, Oxford University
Press, Delhi.
Gangadharan, L., Valenzuela, M.R., 2001, Interrelationships between income, health and the
environment: extending the Environmental Kuznets Curve hypothesis, Ecological Economics n.
36, pp 513-531.
Greenaway, D., Morgan W., Wright P., 2002, Trade liberalisation and growth in developing
countries, Journal of Development Economics Vol. 67, pp. 229-244.
Grossman, G.M., Krueger, A.B., Economic growth and the environment, Quarterly Journal of
Economics, Vol. 1, 1995, pp. 353-377.
Gylfason, T., 2001, Natural resources, education, and economic development, European Economic
Review n. 45, pp. 847-859.
Hallak J.C. Levinsohn J., 2004, Fooling ourselves: evaluating the globalization and growth debate,
NBER Working Paper n. 10244.
Hamilton, K., 2000, Genuine Savings as a Sustainability Indicator, Environmental Economic Series n. 77,
The World Bank, Washington DC.
Hamilton K., Clemens M., 1999, Genuine Savings Rates in Developing Countries, World Bank
Economic Review Vol. 13 (2), pp. 333-356.
Hertel T. W., Martin W., Liberalizing Agriculture and Manufactures in a Millennium Round:
Implications for Developing Countries, The World Economy Vol. 23 (4), pp. 455-469.
Hettige, H., Mani, M., Wheeler, D., 1998, Industrial pollution in economic development: Kuznets
revisited,Washington DC, The World Bank, Environmentally Sustainable Development Policy Research
Working Papers n. 1876.
Hill, R. J., Magnani, E., 2002, An exploration of the conceptual and empirical basis of the
environmental Kuznets curve, Australian Economic Papers, vol. 41, n. 2, pp.239-254.
Isham, J., Woolcock, M., Pritchett, L., Busby, G., 2003, The Varieties of Resource Experience: How
Natural Resource Export Structures Affect the Political Economy of Economic Growth,
Middlebury College Economics Discussion Paper n. 08, Middlebury, Vermont.
Kaufman, D., Kraay, A., Mastruzzi, M., 2003, Governance Matters III: Governance Indicators for 1996-2002,
The World Bank, Washington DC.
Leite, C., Weidmann, J., 1999, Does Mother Nature Corrupt? Natural Resources, Corruption, and
Economic Growth, IMF Working Paper n. 85, International Monetary Found, Washington DC.
Magnani E., 2000, The Environmental Kuznets Curve, environmental protection policy and income
distribution, Ecological Economics, n. 32, pp. 431-443.
Martin, W., 2001, Trade Policies, Developing Countries, and Globalization, Working Paper World
Bank Development Research Group, Washington DC.
Matsen, E., Torvik, R., 2005, Optimal Dutch disease, Journal of Development Economics, n. 78, pp. 494515.
Mehlum, H., Moene, K., Torvik, R., 2002, Institutions and the resource curse, Department of Economics
Memorandum n. 29, University of Oslo, Norway.
Mehlum, H., Moene, K., Torvik, R., 2005, Cursed by resources or institutions?, Department of
Economics Working Paper n. 10, Norwegian University of Science and Technology, Norway.
Mikesell, R.F., 1997, Explaining the resource curse, with special reference to mineral-exporting
30
countries, Resources Policy, Vol. 23 (4), pp. 191-199.
Moseley P., 2000, Globalisation, Economic Policy and Convergence, The World Economy Vol. 23 (5),
pp. 613-634.
Munasinghe, M., 1999, Is environmental degradation an inevitable consequence of economic growth:
tunneling through the environmental Kuznets curve, Ecological Economics, n. 29, pp. 89-109.
Neumayer, E., 2004, Does the “Resource Curse” hold for Growth in Genuine Income as Well?,
World Development Vol. 32 (10), pp. 1627–1640.
North, D.C., 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance, Cambridge University
Press, Cambridge, U.K.
Papyrakis, R., Gerlagh, R., 2004, The resource curse hypothesis and its transmission channels,
Journal of Comparative Economics n. 32, pp. 181-193.
Ranis, G., Stewart, F., Ramirez, A., 2000, Economic Growth and Human Development, World
Development, Vol. 28 (2), pp. 197-219.
Ravallion, M., 2003, The Debate on Globalization, Poverty and Inequality: Why Measurement
Matters, Working Paper Development Research Group n. 3038, World Bank, Washington DC.
Ravallion, M., 2001, Growth, inequality and poverty: looking beyond averages, World Development,
Vol. 29 (11), pp. 1803-15.
Robeyns, I., 2005, The Capability Approach: A Theoretical Survey, Journal of Human Development, 6(1),
pp. 93-114.
Rodríguez, F., Rodrik, D., 2001, Trade policy and economic growth: a skeptic's guide to the crossnational evidence, in Bernanke B.S. and Rogoff K. (eds.), NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000 , pp.
261-325.
Rodrik, D, 2000, Trade Policy Reform as Institutional reform, Working Paper Harvard University.
Rodrik, D., 1998, Globalisation, social conflict and economic growth, The World Economy, Vol. 21 (2),
pp. 143-58.
Ross, M.L., 1999, The political economy of the resource curse, World Politics n. 51, pp. 297-322.
Sachs, J.D., Warner, A.M., 2001, The curse of natural resources, European Economic Review n. 45, pp.
827-838.
Sachs, J.D., Warner, A.M., 1999, The big push, natural resource booms and growth, Journal of
Development Economics, Vol. 59, pp. 43-76.
Sachs, J.D., Warner, A.M., 1995a, Natural resource abundance and economic growth, NBER Working
Paper n. 5398, Cambridge, MA.
Sachs, J.D., Warner, A.M., 1995b, Economic Reform and the Process of Global Integration,
Brookings Paper on Economic Activity, Vol. 1, pp. 1-118.
Sala-i-Martin, X., Subramanian, A., 2003, Addressing the Natural Resource Curse: An Illustration
from Nigeria, IMF Working Paper n. 139, International Monetary Fund, Washington DC.
Sarraf, M., Jiwanji, M., 2001, Beating the resource Curse. The case of Botswana, Environmental
Economics Series n. 83, World Bank, Washington DC.
Selden, T.M., Song, D., 1994, Environmental quality and development: is there a Kuznets curve for
air pollution emissions? , Journal of Environmental Economics and Management, n. 27, pp. 147-162.
Sen, A.K., 1979, Personal Utilities and public judgments: or what’s wrong with the welfare
economics, Economic Journal Vol. 89 (335), pp. 537-558.
Sen, A.K., 1982, Choice Welfare and Measurement, Cambridge, MIT Press.
Sen, A.K., 1983, Development: Which Way Now?, Economic Journal n. 93, pp. 745-62.
Sen, A.K., 1984, Resources, Values and Development, Blackwell Publisher, Oxford.
Sen, A.K., 1985, Commodities and Capabilities, Amsterdam North Holland.
Sen, A.K., 1992, Inequality Re-examined, Claredon Press, Oxford.
Sen, A.K., 1999, Development as Freedom, New York, Random House.
31
Sen, A.K., 2000, The ends and means of sustainability, Key note Address at the International
Conference on Transition to Sustainability, Tokyo, May 2000.
Shafik, N., 1994, Economic Development and Environmental Quality: an econometric analysis,
Oxford Economic Papers, n. 46, pp. 757-773.
Sokoloff, K.L., Engerman, S.L., 2000, History Lessons: Institutions, Factors Endowments, and Paths
of Development in the New World, Journal of Economic Perspectives Vol. 14 (3), pp. 217-232.
Stern, D.I., Common, M.S., 2001, Is There an Environmental Kuznets Curve for Sulfur?, Journal of
Environmental Economics and Management, Vol. 41 (2), pp. 162-178.
Stern, D.I., Common, M.S., Barbier, E.B., 1996, Economic Growth and Environmental Degradation:
The Environmental Kuznets Curve and Sustainable Development, World Development, Vol. 24. (7),
pp. 1151-1160.
Stiglitz, J. E., 2000, Capital Market Liberalization, Economic Growth, and Instability, World
Development Vol. 28 (6), pp. 1075-1086.
Suri, V., Chapman, D., 1998, Economic growth, trade and energy: implications for the
Environmental Kuznets Curve, Ecological Economics, n. 25, pp. 195-208.
Tisdell, C., 2001, Globalisation and sustainability: environmental Kuznets curve and the WTO,
Ecological Economics n. 39, pp. 185-196.
Torvik, R., 2001, Learning by doing and the Dutch disease, European Economic Review n. 45, pp. 285386.
Torvik, R., 2002, Natural resources, rent seeking and welfare, Journal of Development Economics n. 67,
pp. 455-470.
UNDP, Human Development Report 1990-2004, United Nations Development Programme, Oxford
University Press.
Van Wijnbergen, 1984, The ‘Dutch disease’: A Disease After All?, The Economic Journal, Vol. 94 (373),
pp. 41-55.
Vincent J.R., 1997, Testing for environmental Kuznets curves within a developing countries,
Environment and Development Economics Vol. 2, pp. 417-431.
Winters, A., 2004, Trade liberalisation and economic performance: an overview, The Economic Journal
n. 114, pp. 4-21.
World Bank, World Development Indicators, 2004, The World Bank, Washington DC.
World Commission on Environment and Development (WCED), 1987, Our common future, Oxford
University Press, Great Britain.
32
APPENDIX A
Table A1: Data sources and definitions
EG
Initial GDP
Economic Growth, annual growth rate of GDP per capita (constant 1995 $), 1970-2003
Natural logarithm of GDP per capita (constant 1995 $), 1970
Fraction of years in which the country is rated as an open economy (Sachs & Warner,
OPENNESS
1995b)
Natural logarithm of Foreign direct investment, net inflows (% of GDP) average 1970FDI
2003
INFLATION
Natural logarithm of Inflation (GDP deflator), average 1970-2003
INVESTMENTS
Natural logarithm of Gross private capital flows (% of GDP) average 1970-2003
GE
Government Effectiveness (Kauffman et al., 2003)
RL
Rule of Law (Kauffman et al., 2003)
IQ
Quality of Institutions, average value of Six Indicators provided by (Kauffman et al., 2003)
Initial LIFE EXPECT. Life expectancy at birth (UNDP-HDR normalization criterion), 1970
Initial SEC. EDU.
Gross secondary enrollment ratio, (UNDP-HDR normalization criterion), 1970
Change LIFE EXPECT. Change in life expectancy at birth, 1970-2002
Change SEC. EDU.
Change in gross secondary enrollment ratio, 1970-2002
DIFFUSE
Diffuse resources (Agriculture + Food) as % of GDP, average 1970-1975
POINT
Point resources (Oil + Minerals) as % of GDP, average 1970-1975
TOT-RES
Total Natural Resources as % of GDP, average 1970-1975
GDP
Natural logarithm of GDP per capita (constant 1995 $)
HDI
Human Development Index, standard UNDP methodology
HDIM
HDI without GDP Index
TRADE
Natural logarithm of Trade (imports + exports) as % of GDP
MANUF.
Natural logarithm of Industry, value added (% of GDP)
GS
Natural logarithm of Genuine Saving per capita (constant 1995 $)
Natural logarithm of CO2 emissions (ton. per capita)
CO2
33
NOTE DI LAVORO DELLA FONDAZIONE ENI ENRICO MATTEI
Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei Working Paper Series
Our Note di Lavoro are available on the Internet at the following addresses:
https://www.feem.it/Feem/Pub/Publications/WPapers/default.html
https://www.ssrn.com/link/feem.html
https://www.repec.org
https://agecon.lib.umn.edu
NOTE DI LAVORO PUBLISHED IN 2006
SIEV
1.2006
CCMP
2.2006
CCMP
KTHC
3.2006
4.2006
SIEV
5.2006
CCMP
6.2006
PRCG
SIEV
CTN
CTN
NRM
7.2006
8.2006
9.2006
10.2006
11.2006
NRM
12.2006
CCMP
KTHC
KTHC
CSRM
13.2006
14.2006
15.2006
16.2006
CCMP
17.2006
IEM
CTN
18.2006
19.2006
CCMP
20.2006
SIEV
21.2006
CCMP
22.2006
NRM
23.2006
NRM
24.2006
SIEV
25.2006
SIEV
26.2006
KTHC
27.2006
CCMP
28.2006
IEM
29.2006
KTHC
ETA
30.2006
31.2006
IEM
32.2006
NRM
33.2006
CTN
34.2006
IEM
35.2006
Anna ALBERINI: Determinants and Effects on Property Values of Participation in Voluntary Cleanup Programs:
The Case of Colorado
Valentina BOSETTI, Carlo CARRARO and Marzio GALEOTTI: Stabilisation Targets, Technical Change and the
Macroeconomic Costs of Climate Change Control
Roberto ROSON: Introducing Imperfect Competition in CGE Models: Technical Aspects and Implications
Sergio VERGALLI: The Role of Community in Migration Dynamics
Fabio GRAZI, Jeroen C.J.M. van den BERGH and Piet RIETVELD: Modeling Spatial Sustainability: Spatial
Welfare Economics versus Ecological Footprint
Olivier DESCHENES and Michael GREENSTONE: The Economic Impacts of Climate Change: Evidence from
Agricultural Profits and Random Fluctuations in Weather
Michele MORETTO and Paola VALBONESE: Firm Regulation and Profit-Sharing: A Real Option Approach
Anna ALBERINI and Aline CHIABAI: Discount Rates in Risk v. Money and Money v. Money Tradeoffs
Jon X. EGUIA: United We Vote
Shao CHIN SUNG and Dinko DIMITRO: A Taxonomy of Myopic Stability Concepts for Hedonic Games
Fabio CERINA (lxxviii): Tourism Specialization and Sustainability: A Long-Run Policy Analysis
Valentina BOSETTI, Mariaester CASSINELLI and Alessandro LANZA (lxxviii): Benchmarking in Tourism
Destination, Keeping in Mind the Sustainable Paradigm
Jens HORBACH: Determinants of Environmental Innovation – New Evidence from German Panel Data Sources
Fabio SABATINI: Social Capital, Public Spending and the Quality of Economic Development: The Case of Italy
Fabio SABATINI: The Empirics of Social Capital and Economic Development: A Critical Perspective
Giuseppe DI VITA: Corruption, Exogenous Changes in Incentives and Deterrence
Rob B. DELLINK and Marjan W. HOFKES: The Timing of National Greenhouse Gas Emission Reductions in
the Presence of Other Environmental Policies
Philippe QUIRION: Distributional Impacts of Energy-Efficiency Certificates Vs. Taxes and Standards
Somdeb LAHIRI: A Weak Bargaining Set for Contract Choice Problems
Massimiliano MAZZANTI and Roberto ZOBOLI: Examining the Factors Influencing Environmental
Innovations
Y. Hossein FARZIN and Ken-ICHI AKAO: Non-pecuniary Work Incentive and Labor Supply
Marzio GALEOTTI, Matteo MANERA and Alessandro LANZA: On the Robustness of Robustness Checks of the
Environmental Kuznets Curve
Y. Hossein FARZIN and Ken-ICHI AKAO: When is it Optimal to Exhaust a Resource in a Finite Time?
Y. Hossein FARZIN and Ken-ICHI AKAO: Non-pecuniary Value of Employment and Natural Resource
Extinction
Lucia VERGANO and Paulo A.L.D. NUNES: Analysis and Evaluation of Ecosystem Resilience: An Economic
Perspective
Danny CAMPBELL, W. George HUTCHINSON and Riccardo SCARPA: Using Discrete Choice Experiments to
Derive Individual-Specific WTP Estimates for Landscape Improvements under Agri-Environmental Schemes
Evidence from the Rural Environment Protection Scheme in Ireland
Vincent M. OTTO, Timo KUOSMANEN and Ekko C. van IERLAND: Estimating Feedback Effect in Technical
Change: A Frontier Approach
Giovanni BELLA: Uniqueness and Indeterminacy of Equilibria in a Model with Polluting Emissions
Alessandro COLOGNI and Matteo MANERA: The Asymmetric Effects of Oil Shocks on Output Growth: A
Markov-Switching Analysis for the G-7 Countries
Fabio SABATINI: Social Capital and Labour Productivity in Italy
Andrea GALLICE (lxxix): Predicting one Shot Play in 2x2 Games Using Beliefs Based on Minimax Regret
Andrea BIGANO and Paul SHEEHAN: Assessing the Risk of Oil Spills in the Mediterranean: the Case of the
Route from the Black Sea to Italy
Rinaldo BRAU and Davide CAO (lxxviii): Uncovering the Macrostructure of Tourists’ Preferences. A Choice
Experiment Analysis of Tourism Demand to Sardinia
Parkash CHANDER and Henry TULKENS: Cooperation, Stability and Self-Enforcement in International
Environmental Agreements: A Conceptual Discussion
Valeria COSTANTINI and Salvatore MONNI: Environment, Human Development and Economic Growth
(lxxviii) This paper was presented at the Second International Conference on "Tourism and Sustainable
Economic Development - Macro and Micro Economic Issues" jointly organised by CRENoS (Università
di Cagliari and Sassari, Italy) and Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei, Italy, and supported by the World Bank,
Chia, Italy, 16-17 September 2005.
(lxxix) This paper was presented at the International Workshop on "Economic Theory and Experimental
Economics" jointly organised by SET (Center for advanced Studies in Economic Theory, University of
Milano-Bicocca) and Fondazione Eni Enrico Mattei, Italy, Milan, 20-23 November 2005. The Workshop
was co-sponsored by CISEPS (Center for Interdisciplinary Studies in Economics and Social Sciences,
University of Milan-Bicocca).
2006 SERIES
CCMP
Climate Change Modelling and Policy (Editor: Marzio Galeotti )
SIEV
Sustainability Indicators and Environmental Valuation (Editor: Anna Alberini)
NRM
Natural Resources Management (Editor: Carlo Giupponi)
KTHC
Knowledge, Technology, Human Capital (Editor: Gianmarco Ottaviano)
IEM
International Energy Markets (Editor: Anil Markandya)
CSRM
Corporate Social Responsibility and Sustainable Management (Editor: Sabina Ratti)
PRCG
Privatisation Regulation Corporate Governance (Editor: Bernardo Bortolotti)
ETA
Economic Theory and Applications (Editor: Carlo Carraro)
CTN
Coalition Theory Network