Academia.eduAcademia.edu

Transnational Non-state Regulatory Regimes

What do Apple’s Supplier Responsibility program, the U.K.-based Internet Watch Foundation, and the Motion Picture Association of America’s (MPAA) campaign against unauthorized downloads of movies have in common? They are examples of transnational non-state regulatory regimes. This type of regulation encompasses a broad array of regulatory arrangements carried out by corporate actors, non-governmental organizations, and civil-society groups working alone or in collaboration. Regulation in this context refers broadly to the means that guide any activity, individual or institution to behave according to formal or informal rules (Picciotto 2002: 1). Given the diversity of actors and activities comprising this type of regulation, there is no standard definition for transnational non-state regulation. It can be broadly understood as non-state actors making, implementing, and/or enforcing rules and standards across national borders. Some arrangements may comprise a single company or industry, while others cut across industry sectors or involve multiple business and civil-society stakeholders who represent a range of interests. Actors may employ formal legal mechanisms, such as national or international laws, as well as informal processes like non-legally binding certification programs or codes of conducts. They may have different motivations and interests for becoming involved in the regulatory endeavors and diverse goals. Participants may have profit-oriented goals, such as reducing regulatory duplication to strengthen corporate performance, or efforts may be public-oriented to target problems like pollution or child labour. Apple’s Supplier Responsibility program, for instance, in which the company may terminate its contracts with suppliers that do not comply with its labour and environmental standards, is designed to burnish Apple’s credentials as a good corporate citizen. The MPAA pressures Internet firms, particularly Google, to make it more difficult for people to find and download unauthorized versions of copyrighted movies. In contrast, the Internet Watch Foundation is a non-profit organization that works with Internet firms like Google and PayPal to remove child pornography from websites around the world. This chapter explores how transnational non-state regulation operates, particularly the ways in which non-state actors can make and enforce rules, and then outlines the challenges raised by this type of regulation. First, the chapter introduces the concept of regimes to provide a way to understand this type of regulation and then describes how non-state actors interact with states. Then the chapter outlines why transnational non-state regulation emerges before turning to discuss how non-state actors draw upon varying forms of authority to regulate. Third, the chapter explores the varying degrees of involvements states may have with transnational non-state regulatory regimes. The chapter then discusses the benefits and challenges of this type of regulation before providing a brief conclusion.

Natasha Tusikov 1 Transnational Non-state Regulatory Regimes by Natasha Tusikov In Peter Drahos and Jeroen van der Heijden, eds. Regulation, Institutions, Networks. Canberra: Australian National University Press: forthcoming What do Apple’s Supplier Responsibility program, the U.K.-based Internet Watch Foundation, and the Motion Picture Association of America’s (MPAA) campaign against unauthorized downloads of movies have in common? They are examples of transnational non-state regulatory regimes. This type of regulation encompasses a broad array of regulatory arrangements carried out by corporate actors, non-governmental organizations, and civil-society groups working alone or in collaboration. Regulation in this context refers broadly to the means that guide any activity, individual or institution to behave according to formal or informal rules (Picciotto 2002: 1). Given the diversity of actors and activities comprising this type of regulation, there is no standard definition for transnational non-state regulation. It can be broadly understood as non-state actors making, implementing, and/or enforcing rules and standards across national borders. Some arrangements may comprise a single company or industry, while others cut across industry sectors or involve multiple business and civil-society stakeholders who represent a range of interests. Actors may employ formal legal mechanisms, such as national or international laws, as well as informal processes like non-legally binding certification programs or codes of conducts. They may have different motivations and interests for becoming involved in the regulatory endeavors and diverse goals. Participants may have profit-oriented goals, such as reducing regulatory duplication to strengthen corporate performance, or efforts may be public-oriented to target problems like pollution or child labour. Apple’s Supplier Responsibility program, for instance, in which the company may terminate its contracts with suppliers that do not comply with its labour and environmental standards, is designed to burnish Apple’s credentials as a good corporate citizen. The MPAA pressures Internet firms, particularly Google, to make it more difficult for people to find and download unauthorized versions of copyrighted movies. In contrast, the Internet Watch Foundation is a non-profit organization that works with Internet firms like Google and PayPal to remove child pornography from websites around the world. The rest of the chapter explores how transnational non-state regulation operates, particularly the ways in which non-state actors can make and enforce rules, and then outlines the challenges raised by this type of regulation. First, the chapter introduces the concept of regimes to provide a way to understand this type of regulation and then describes how non-state actors interact with states. Then the chapter outlines why transnational non-state regulation emerges before turning to discuss how non-state actors draw upon varying forms of authority to regulate. Third, the chapter explores the varying degrees of involvements states may have with transnational non-state regulatory regimes. The chapter then discusses the benefits and challenges of this type of regulation before providing a brief conclusion. Regimes and States Given the diversity of actors, rules, and interests comprising many instances of transnational non-state regulation, the concept of regimes provides a useful analytical framework. Regimes can be understood as “the full set of actors, institutions, norms and rules” comprising a particular regulatory arrangement (Eberlein and Grande 2005:91). Scholars from the fields of international relations, socio-legal studies and regulatory Natasha Tusikov 2 theory employ the concept of regimes to explain the ways in which non-state actors can set and enforce rules and standards transnationally, and explore their varying interests in participating in such regimes (see e.g., Cutler et al. 1999). The concept is useful because it explicitly acknowledges the role of non-state actors and recognizes that regulation may involve “soft law” or informal governance practices, such as certification practices or industry-derived codes of conduct, along with other rule-making mechanisms like contracts or statutory laws. As regime analysis considers the full ensemble of actors, interests and rules comprising regulatory efforts, they are also valuable to track similarities and differences among actors’ material and ideational interests in relation to the governance of a particular issue. Actors may have conflicting, sometimes irreconcilable differences that shape the composition and function of governance arrangements. Regulation that materially benefits one party can impose costs on the other. In terms of their scope, regimes may be considered transnational according to the reach of their rule-setting actors, the level of the rule-setting institutions, the span of the rules themselves, or a combination of these factors (Mügge 2006:179). Even though actors within a regime may operate transnationally through the scope of its actors or rules, the regime may have distinct territorial roots or localized characteristics (Graz and Nölke 2008). These local roots may infuse a regime with characteristics that shape its character or operation. Prominent rule-making actors, for example, may all be based within the global north creating rules that govern how transnational mining companies operate in the global south (see Dashwood 2012). Using regimes can help trace the particular historical and socio-cultural context from which actors emerged to form particular regulatory arrangements. From its name, it would appear that the state has very little or even no role in transnational non-state regulation. However, this is not the case. To understand the role of states in this type of regulation, it is important to outline briefly how states can strategically deploy their power through regulation. One way to consider how this occurs is through the framework of regulatory capitalism, which is prominently associated with John Braithwaite and David Levi-Faur, among other regulatory theorists (see Levi-Faur this volume). In regulatory capitalism, the state takes on a meta-regulatory role: it directs, oversees and spurs on regulation and, in doing so, governs through regulation (see LeviFaur 2013). The oft-quoted metaphor of “steering” and “rowing” aptly describes the state’s meta-regulation. In this nautical image, the state strategically “steers” or directs regulatory efforts while non-state actors take on the state’s traditional task of “rowing” by creating and operating various regulatory arrangements (Osborne and Gaebler 1992). States may play a strong, direct role by facilitating regulatory efforts, proscribing specific goals, or mandating the use of certain monitoring and enforcement mechanisms. They may also govern indirectly by empowering non-state actors to enact rules, shaping discourse and distributing resources (Levi-Faur 2013:39). States may also provide incentives to corporate and civil-society actors to create or enforce certain rules and standards (see Gunningham and Grabosky this volume). When there are conflicts among actors or appeals to governments for assistance, states can arbitrate among competing non-state interests. Corporate actors, for example, may lobby a state for a particular regulatory approach that is opposed by civil-society groups that advocate different measures. Not all actors have equal resources to persuade states to support their regulatory preferences or command the same degree of influence in shaping state policymaking processes. Some large corporate actors have the capacity to lobby for Natasha Tusikov 3 policies that benefit their interests and create their own rules and standards, both domestically and transnationally to regulate their individual corporations, their global supply chains, or even industry sectors. Similarly, not all states have an equal capacity to influence, stimulate or control regulatory efforts by non-state actors, particularly megacorporate actors. To understand why states privilege certain interests, it is helpful to consider state as embedded in the economic and social order: the state and society mutually constitute one another (Underhill 2003). Simply put, there is a flow of ideas between the state and society in which each shapes the other. States grant a role in policymaking to interests groups that put forward competing and complementary ideas to articulate problems, propose remedies, and shape policies. States determine which actors are more authoritative, lend legitimacy to some interests over others, and privilege certain policies (Hall 1993: 288). It is important to underline that states retain interests and goals that are distinct from its lobbyists even as those actors endeavour to shape governments’ priorities and policymaking. States retain a capacity to act autonomously even as they accord interest groups opportunities to shape policymaking (Hall 1993). Origins and Authority One of the principal reasons that non-state actors may form transnational regulatory arrangements is because states are perceived to be incapable or unwilling to provide transnational governance on certain issues. Corporate actors or civil-society groups may also turn to non-state regulation if states are not addressing problems in ways that the non-state actors consider appropriate. By creating standards and rules privately, nonstate actors can work to address gaps in regulation or harmonise competing or uneven rules internationally in order to make governance efforts more effective (Cafaggi 2012). Multinational corporations working alongside civil-society groups, for example, have created international standards in relation to the commercial use and preservation of forests (see Meidinger 2002). Similarly, child-protection advocates, together with law enforcement and industry groups, created the Internet Watch Foundation to target child pornography hosted anywhere on the Internet. Corporate actors may strategically embrace non-state regulation in order to pre-empt government regulation or water down existing rules (Cutler et al. 1999). There may be normative reasons for corporate actors’ adoption of private rules, such as to repair or safeguard their reputations. For example, following criticism of Apple’s supply-chain practices, the company began using thirdparty auditors to ensure the tantalum, which is a valuable metal, used in its products was obtained from conflict-free countries in Africa (see Apple 2014). Transnational non-state regulatory regimes vary widely in the source of their authority to set or enforce rules and standards. Actors within such regimes generally exercise “autonomous regulatory power or implemen[t] delegated power, conferred by international law or by national legislation” (Cafaggi 2010:1). In terms of delegated authority, states may designate responsibility for monitoring or enforcing criminal or civil laws to non-state actors, or direct those actors to perform specific duties such as inspections or audits (see Scott 2002). In many countries private security companies, like the U.K.-based multinational Serco Group, have state-delegated authority to transport, guard and house prisoners. A common form of autonomous regulatory authority comes from contracts. Corporations can set rules or standards within their supply chains through contracts with their manufacturers and suppliers, for instance, in relation to labour or environmental standards (see e.g., Apple 2014). Companies that wish to become suppliers to Apple, for example, must abide by its environmental and Natasha Tusikov 4 labour conditions and demonstrate compliance in third-party audits or risk losing contracts. States, however, can intervene in commercial contracts if they violate laws, such as those prohibiting anti-competitive behaviour. Non-state actors may lack a formal legal authority to govern and instead must persuade – or pressure – others to accept their rules or comply with their regulatory programs. To do so, they can draw upon their resources and put forward their policies as the best approach. These are examples of structural authority and discursive authority and one may be employed to strengthen the other. Structural authority, which is based upon Susan Strange’s (1997) notion of structural power, refers to transnational corporate actors’ capacity to influence government policymaking by threatening to relocate investment or employment. It also encompasses those actors’ ability to control access to or the use of certain markets and to govern their supply chains, particularly when they dominate markets (see Fuchs and Kalfagianni 2010). Visa, MasterCard and PayPal, for example, dominate the online payment market, while Google commands the search market, which means that these companies have considerable capacity to act as online regulators. Discursive authority, in contrast, refers to actors’ ability to frame and shape the meaning of ideas to affect how people understand issues and influence policymaking (Fuchs 2007). Using this capacity to shape ideas, non-state actors may also invoke moral and technical authority to argue for their preferred regulatory approach. Moral authority involves drawing broadly accepted values, while technical authority involves claims to specialized or expert knowledge or skills, or objective advice (Avant, Finnemore, and Sell 2010). The Internet Watch Foundation, for instance, claims moral authority when it demands that Internet firms like Yahoo and Google join its ranks to target the online distribution of child pornography (see Laidlaw 2010). The MPAA, meanwhile, invokes both moral and technical authority. It claims to protect the copyright of its members’ movies from “theft”1 and, invoking its status as the trade body for the movie industry, the MPAA designs policies to deter the unauthorized downloads of movies (see Brandom 2014). Non-state actors without formal legal authority may create regulatory regimes based upon informal measures, such as non-legally binding certification programs and corporate social responsibility codes. For example, the Forestry Stewardship Council (FSC), which is comprised of business, social and environmental interests, certifies forestry companies, including manufacturers and retailers as compliant with the FSC’s standards on sustainability and environmental protection (see Meidinger 2002). Corporate social responsibility codes are often joint agreements between civil-society organizations and corporations to address certain problems resulting from poor industry practices, such as pollution, or to improve industry practices in particular areas, such as human rights or labour standards (see Dashwood 2012). Certification and corporate social responsibility programs are generally intended to marry private business interests with public-interests goals. They are designed (whether or not they are effective) to benefit the interests of the regulated, which are primarily business entities, and serve the collective interest through efforts to protect human rights, among other programs. In addition to the arrangements described above among non-state actors, there is another that is gaining prominence – non-legally binding “voluntary” agreements. These 1 Proponents of stronger protection for copyright have long successfully framed copyright infringement as “theft,” an effective strategy that casts infringement as a serious crime that necessitates a corresponding serious enforcement response (see Drahos and Braithwaite 2002). Natasha Tusikov 5 agreements are voluntary in the sense that they are not based on legislation or legal contracts but on non-binding guidelines or sets of industry-derived “best practices.” The term “voluntary,” however, can be misleading as states can exert considerable coercive pressure to force non-state actors to join the arrangements or abide by their decisions. Other non-state actors may also pressure stakeholders to join the agreements by threatening legal action or withholding business deals. Non-legally binding agreements are increasingly used to regulate digital-copyright infringement (e.g., unauthorized downloads of music and movies) and the online sale of counterfeit goods, which is a form of trademark infringement. In these non-binding agreements, rights holders of intellectual property – typically large multinational companies like Nike or Sony – work with Internet firms like PayPal to stop the online distribution of copyright-infringing and counterfeit goods (Tusikov 2014). Degrees of State Involvement Government involvement in transnational non-state regulation varies according to the issue under regulation, the nature of the regulatory arrangement, and the degree of reliance, if any, upon the state. As discussed earlier in the chapter, states retain the authority in the regulatory capitalism framework to mandate, shape, endorse or reject non-state regulatory efforts, as well as to delegate authority to non-state actors (see Levi-Faur 2013; Levi-Faur this volume). States may not necessarily be aware of or equally attentive to all cases of non-state regulation, particularly where its interests are not affected or private actors do not seek state involvement. For example, corporate social responsibility programs organized among corporations and non-governmental organisations to strengthen standards relating to environmental protection may not elicit attention by governments. As well, states vary widely in their capacity to influence and their degree of involvement in transnational non-state regulation. Transnational non-state regulatory regimes may have little, if any, state involvement. Where there is relative agreement among stakeholders in relation to the regime, or if there are suitable incentives offered (or penalties credibly threatened), there may few interactions with state actors. This is the case when powerful multinational companies, such as Wal-Mart or Apple, contractually require their suppliers to adhere to specific environmental, labour or quality control standards. Suppliers are under considerable pressure to accept these contracts as they have few alternatives given the significant market share commanded by Wal-Mart and Apple. Further, the penalties for violation are serious. Suppliers found in violation of the contracts can be terminated as preferred suppliers and, given the market dominance of such firms, this means the suppliers essentially lose their license “to participate in the global market” (Fuchs and Kalfagianni 2010:3). Contract-based regimes require little direct interaction with the state, as the corporations set and enforce rules through their supply chains. However, corporations’ use of legal contracts to enforce rules and standards means that they rely indirectly upon state legal systems. Similarly, in the case of a disagreement among regime participants, actors have recourse to pursue the matter in the relevant national legal jurisdiction. When non-state actors lack a contractual or statutory basis in their regime, they can attempt to persuade or pressure others to conform to their rules. They can draw upon their structural and discursive authority by employing litigation or promising to grant or withhold business deals. If these methods fail, actors may turn to the state or its structures, although actors may have different preferences as to the degree and nature of state involvement (Cafaggi 2010). Faced with non-compliant actors, a regime’s actors can, in some situations, turn to national laws or public institutions to seek compliance or Natasha Tusikov 6 use the threat of civil or criminal remedies to motivate compliance with the regime’s rules, standards or codes. They may also seek direct assistance from state actors. Members of transnational regime may lobby states to support or facilitate a particular regulatory agenda, or to prod reluctant actors into cooperating with the regime. The success of these requests depends on the states’ interests in the regime, as well as the states’ capacity and willingness to intervene. The distribution of power among non-state actors, however, is temporal as interests may shift over time or as a different sets of actors may assume greater power. Further, the state may weaken or revoke its recognition of the regulatory arrangement, non-state actors can lose credibility from their stakeholders or those they govern, rivals may contest the regime’s legitimacy (Avant, Finnemore, and Sell 2010). Some requests for state assistance resonant with the state or align more closely with its interests than others. Both the Internet Watch Foundation and the MPAA enjoy a close relationship with the U.K. and U.S. governments, respectively. The U.K. government is strongly supportive of the Internet Watch Foundation’s enforcement strategy in which Internet firms, including Google, Yahoo, Twitter and PayPal, block access to websites suspected of hosting child pornography content to deter individuals from accessing those websites (see Internet Watch Foundation 2013). Similarly, the MPAA has a long, successful history of shaping U.S. – and international – policymaking in relation to the ever-increasing protection of copyright (see Brandom 2014; Drahos and Braithwaite). For Apple, in contrast, pressure to improve the company’s labour and environmental standards came primarily from non-governmental organizations and its customers (Apple Press Info 2012). In cases where states have interests in the subject of regulation, they may exert direct, even coercive pressure on non-state actors to convince them to participate in transnational non-state regulatory regimes. For example, in the United States and the United Kingdom, government officials warned Internet firms that they could expect legislation or legal action to force their compliance if they did not adopt non-legally binding agreements with rights holders to address the online distribution of copyright-infringing and counterfeit goods (Tusikov 2014). Given this coercion, the nonlegally binding agreements are not voluntary but a form of enforced regulation. When state actors intervene in non-state regulation by supporting, facilitating, or even directly creating a particular regulatory arrangement, they legitimize the authority of the nonstate actors to govern and the regime. Benefits and Challenges of Transnational Non-state Regulation Transnational non-state regulation can offer certain benefits. Governments may perceive non-state actors, particularly corporations, as more responsive, cost-effective and efficient regulators than government agencies in certain areas, or has having specialized technical knowledge, industry or sector familiarity and greater access to markets (see Cutler et al. 1999). Such regulation can be more responsive and adaptive to changes in technology or circumstances than legislation, international law or trade agreements (Cafaggi 2012). As contracts and non-legally binding agreements can be more flexible than law, non-state actors may be more willing to join regulatory arrangements using these mechanisms as they may have more of an ability to provide input or amend them to suit their needs. The regime can be expanded or contracted as needed and its rules amended to reflecting changing circumstances or stakeholders’ needs. Nongovernmental and civil-society organizations can have greater power to push corporate – or even state – actors to address public-oriented goals, such as protection of the environment or consumers’ rights through non-state regulatory regimes. This is particularly the case when civil-society actors can capitalize upon corporations’ fear of Natasha Tusikov 7 scandal and damage to their reputations, as was the case with Apple and criticism of its labour practices (see Apple Press Info 2012). Working outside more traditional legal processes can enable non-state actors to address problems that states are unwilling or incapable of addressing alone, at least in ways that non-state actors may prefer. For example, partnerships with Internet firms based upon non-binding agreements enable the MPAA and Internet Watch Foundation to extend their enforcement reach globally through the Internet firms’ global operations. Working with government officials from various jurisdictions using their national laws would be much more time consuming and difficult. Transnational non-state regulation can also provide ways to harmonize rules or address gaps or inconsistencies in national laws (see Cafaggi 2010). Non-state efforts in the forestry and food industries attempt to address these problems through the use of industry certification programs and supplychain contracts (see Fuchs and Kalfigianni 2010; Meidinger 2002). Although non-state regulation is often associated with soft law, such as certification programs, it can deliver formidable sanctions. Suppliers who violate their supply-chain agreements, for example, can lose lucrative contracts. For states, transnational non-state regulation can be useful as it enables them to reach beyond their traditional jurisdictional boundaries or to regulate in ways or at a scale that are typically unfeasible for government agencies. By supporting or facilitating non-state regulation, states can capitalize upon or influence the production, implementation and enforcement of rules in particular sectors or issues that align with their interests. Nonstate regulation can also provide avenues for states to side step failed, stalled, unworkable, or controversial legislation or trade agreements and achieve similar, or even enhanced regulatory outcomes. States can publicly, but selectively, endorse specific efforts, or strategically distance the state by emphasizing the central role of non-state actors in the creation and operation of the regulatory regime. Transnational non-state regulatory regimes raise significant challenges, particularly in terms of accountability and due process. In terms of accountability, it is often difficult for those outside the regime to determine how rules and standards are drafted, the ways they are enforced, or by whom. It may also be difficult to evaluate the regime’s effectiveness in the context of its goals. Regimes may seek to address these problems by publishing annual reports on their activities and achievements (see, e.g., Apple 2014 and Internet Watch Foundation 2013). These reports, however, are often little more than public relations documents that promote the regimes but do not provide the level of detail necessary to evaluate their operation or performance. Transnational non-state regimes also raise broader challenges in terms of accountability. These regimes often reveal global north-south patterns in which influence over governance is concentrated in the global north. Regulatory capitalism tends to describe regimes that are “shaped in North America and Europe [and] are increasingly internationalized and projected globally” (Levi-Faur 2005: 13). This means rules and standards that are generally set in the global north extend internationally to govern people who may have little awareness of the regimes’ existence. Further, governments in the countries in which the regimes operate may little knowledge of or influence over the regimes, even though its governance could affect them. This patterning is echoed in the cases of Apple, the MPAA and Internet Watch Foundation. Apple’s rules, set in its California headquarters, govern its global supply chain, particularly its production activities in China. By tapping into Internet firms with global operations, the MPAA and Natasha Tusikov 8 Internet Watch Foundation are able to carry out worldwide enforcement campaigns against the unauthorized downloads of movies and the distribution of child pornography. The same characteristics that enable non-state regimes to be flexible and responsive to changes in circumstances can impede due-process mechanisms. Appeals processes may be inadequate or difficult to navigate and actors may impose sanctions based upon suspicion, not proof of wrongdoing. Regimes’ participants may use technology to identify and target potentially suspicious behaviour, which raises challenges of wrongful identification and mass policing of legitimate activities and innocent people. The Internet Watch Foundation, for example, compiles a blacklist of websites suspected to be involved in distributing child pornography and instructs the Internet firms participating in its program to block all sites on the list. However, blacklists can – and do – incorrectly block legitimate content and thereby thwart legal activities. The criteria used to blacklist websites and the process for doing so are often closely guarded secrets, as is the case with the Internet Watch Foundation, which also blocks examination of websites it blacklists by outsiders (see Laidlaw 2010). Regulatory efforts based on secretly drafted criteria and unobservable processes raise significant problems in relation to accountability and legitimacy. Conclusion As transnational non-state regulatory regimes comprise a broad array of actors, rules, arrangements, strategies, and interests, it is important to examine each regime’s constituent components. An important element of this analysis is to explore the nature of the regime’s authority, whether actors invoke moral, technical or discursive authority, or how they draw upon their resources to wield structural authority. Further, it is necessary to determine how actors set rules: do they primarily use statutory laws or contracts, nonlegally binding mechanisms, or some combination of these? Related to this, one must examine the degree to which the regime relies upon the state or its structures. State actors may play significant roles in supporting, facilitating or even directly constructing the regime, depending on the degree to which the state’s interests align with those of the regime. As states recognize non-state regimes, they legitimize the regime and its activities. Not all states, however, have equal influence over transnational non-state regimes, nor can all non-state actors equally shape public policymaking. Such regimes often follow a north-south pattern in which rules are set by actors in the global north and then exported worldwide. The three regimes explored throughout the chapter – Apple’s supply-chain program, the Internet Watch Foundation, and the MPAA’s anti-piracy campaign – echo this global north-south configuration. These examples demonstrate the importance of state actors in facilitating and, in certain cases, directly shaping non-state regulation, even coercively pressuring non-state actors’ participation. Given the diversity of transnational non-state regimes and the important issues they regulate, this is a fertile area for future research. Suggested Readings: Eberlein, B., Abbott K.W., Black, J., Meidinger, E., and Wood, S. Transnational business governance interactions: Conceptualization and framework for analysis. Regulation & Governance. 8. p. 1-21. Scott, C. (2012) Beyond Taxonomies of Private Authority in Transnational Regulation. German Law Journal. 13(12). p. 1329-1338. Natasha Tusikov 9 Zumbansen, P. (2011) Neither ‘Public’ nor ‘Private’, ‘National’ nor ‘International’: Transnational Corporate Governance from a Legal Pluralist Perspective. Journal of Law and Society. 38(1). p. 50-75. References Apple. (2014) Supplier Responsibility 2014 Progress Report. Available from: https://www.apple.com/au/supplierresponsibility/pdf/Apple_SR_2014_Progress_Report.pdf. [Accessed 16 May 2014]. Apple Press Info. (2012) Fair Labor Association Begins Inspections of Foxconn. 13 February. Available from: https://www.apple.com/pr/library/2012/02/13Fair-Labor-Association-Begins-Inspectionsof-Foxconn.html. [Accessed: 14 November 2013]. Avant, D.D., Finnemore, M. and Sell, S.K. (eds.) (2010) Who governs the globe? Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Brandom, R. (2014) Project Goliath: Inside Hollywood’s Secret War Against Google. The Verge. 12 December. Available from: https://www.theverge.com/2014/12/12/7382287/project-goliath. [Retrieved 12 December 2014]. Cafaggi, F. (ed.) (2012) Enforcement Of Transnational Regulation: Ensuring Compliance in a Global World. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar Publishing. Cafaggi, F. (2010) New Foundations of Transnational Private Regulation. Private Regulation Series-04. Florence: Robert Schuman Centre For Advanced Studies, European University Institute. Available from: cadmus.eui.eu/bitstream/handle/1814/15284/RSCAS_2010_53.pdf. [Accessed 10 October 2014] Cutler, A.C. Haufler, V. and Porter, T. (1999) Private Authority and International Affairs. Albany: State University of New York Press. Dashwood, H.S. (2012) The Rise of Global Corporate Social Responsibility: Mining and the Spread of Global Norms. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Drahos, P. and Braithwaite, J. (2002) Information Feudalism: Who Owns the Knowledge Economy. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Eberlein, B. and Grande, E. (2005) Beyond delegation: transnational regulatory regimes and the EU regulatory state. Journal of European Public Policy. 12(1). p. 89–112. Fuchs, D. (2007) Business Power in Global Governance. Boulder, CO: Lynne Rienner Publishers. Fuchs, D. and Kalfagianni, A. (2010) The Causes and Consequences of Private Food Governance. Business and Politics. 12(1). p. 37. Natasha Tusikov 10 Graz, J-C and Nölke, A. (2008) Introduction: Beyond the fragmented debate on transnational private governance. Pp. 2-26 in Transnational private governance and its limits, edited by J.C. Graz and A. Nölke. New York: Routledge. Hall, P.A. (1993) Policy Paradigms, Social Learning, and the State: The Case of Economic Policymaking in Britain. Comparative Politics. 25(3). p. 275-296. Internet Watch Foundation. (2013) Internet Watch Foundation Annual and Charity Report 2013. Available from: https://www.iwf.org.uk/accountability/annual-reports/2013annual-report. [Accessed: 14 December 2014]. Laidlaw, E. (2012) The responsibilities of free speech regulators: an analysis of the Internet Watch Foundation. International Journal of Law and Information Technology. 20(4). p. 312-345. Levi-Faur, D. (2005) The Global Diffusion of Regulatory Capitalism. The ANNALS of the American Academy of Political and Social Science. 598. p.12-32. Levi-Faur, D. (2013) The Odyssey of the Regulatory State: From a “Thin” Monomorphic Concept to a “Thick” and Polymorphic Concept. Law & Policy. 35. p. 29-50. Meidinger, E. (2002) Forest Certification as a Global Civil Society Regulatory Institutions. Pp. 265-289 in Social and Political Dimensions of Forest Certification, edited by E. Meidinger, C. Elliott, and G. Oesten. Remagen- Oberwinter: Gupta Books. Mügge, D. (2006) Private-Public Puzzles: Inter-firm competition and transnational private regulation. New Political Economy. 11(2). p. 177-200. Osborne, D and Gaebler, T. (1992) Reinventing Government: the Entrepreneurial Spirit is Transforming the Public Sector. New York: Plume. Picciotto, S. (2011) Regulating Global Corporate Capitalism. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Scott, C. (2002) Private Regulation of the Public Sector: A Neglected Facet of Contemporary Governance. Journal of Law and Society. 29(1). p. 56-76. Strange, S. (1997) The Retreat of the State: The Diffusion of Power in the World Economy. International Journal. 52. p. 366-369. Tusikov, N. (2014) Chokepoints: Internet Intermediaries and the Private Regulation of Counterfeit Goods on the Internet. (The Australian National University: Unpublished PhD Dissertation). Underhill, G.R.D. (2003) States, markets and governance for emerging market economies: private interests, the public good and the legitimacy of the development process. International Affairs. 79. p. 755-781.