A Solo, a Duet, or an Ensemble?
Analysing the Recent Development of
Religious Communities in Contemporary Rural
China
Yu Tao | 陶郁
University of Oxford
This project is funded by
the European Union
A project implemented by
Steinbeis GmbH & Co. KG für
Technologietransfer
© Europe China Research and Advice Network, 2012
This publication may be reproduced for personal and educational use only. Commercial copying, hiring or
lending of this publication is strictly prohibited.
Europe China Research and Advice Network
10 St James’s Square
London SW1Y 4LE
+44 (0) 20 7314 3659
[email protected]
www.euecran.eu
The Europe China Research and Advice Network (ECRAN) is a three-year project funded by the European
Union to provide advice on China to European policy-makers. It aims to establish a wide network of experts
and institutions across Europe who share a common interest in China. For more information, please contact
the ECRAN office:
[email protected]
This essay was selected for publication at the ECRAN Young Researchers’ PhD Student Forum, which took
place at the University of Nottingham on 13 September 2011.
This paper welcomes comments, critiques, and criticisms. The author can be contacted at
[email protected].
The contents of this publication are the sole responsibility of the author(s) and can in no way be taken
to reflect the views of ECRAN or the European Union.
A Solo, a Duet, or an Ensemble? Analysing the Recent Development of Religious
Communities in Contemporary Rural China
Introduction
In contemporary China, a society experiencing rapid economic, social and institutional transition,
religious communities are important due to their international and domestic significance. On the one
hand, with its close links to important political issues such as minority ethnic group unrest, religious
freedom in China has been a hot topic within international human rights debates for decades (Wong
2001; Kolodner 1994); on the other hand, burgeoning religious communities are considered powerful
emerging social forces in China’s domestic political arena, especially at the grassroots level (Chung et
al. 2006; Tsai 2007).
Under such circumstances it is no surprise that discussions of ‘religious freedom’ and ‘religious
harmony’ have frequently appeared in China’s official discourse since 1982, when the Central
Government’s Document No. 19 officially acknowledged the unjust nature of its radical anti-religious
policies between 1957 and 1978 and reconfirmed that ‘the Party’s principal religious policy is to
respect and protect religious freedom’1. Nevertheless, complementary laws and regulations for the
implementation of religious freedom have remained frustratingly insufficient and ambiguous in China
over the past three decades. This ambiguity has created ample space for interpretation, has provided
political opportunity structures for both policy implementers and religious groups,2 and has made it
impossible to assess the development of religious communities in China by simply looking at formal
legal and political institutions at the national level. Accurate empirical data and first-hand local
knowledge are therefore indispensable for understanding the religious community in contemporary
China and its recent developments.
1
The English translation of the Document No 19 (1982) is downloadable from the Centre on Religion and Chinese
Society at Purdue University (https://www.purdue.edu/crcs/itemResources/PRCDoc/pdf/Document_no._19_1982.pdf,
[accessed Mar 5, 2012]).
2
Research on petitioning in rural China has demonstrated how grassroots elites and ordinary people use the
Constitution, laws and official regulations to protect their rights and pursue their demands. Kevin O’Brien and Li
Lianjiang find that petitioning in rural China is more likely to be a success if it is launched and operated by ‘rightful
resisters’, a widely-quoted term that refers to the social actors who ‘frame their claims with reference to protections
implied in ideologies or conferred by policymakers’ (O’Brien & Li 1995; 2005; 2006; O’Brien 1996). Such findings
coincide with Cai Yongshun’s (2002; 2005) research on laid-off workers and Ying Xing’s (2001) research on reservoir
resettlements. Therefore, it is very likely that grassroots religious leaders could also employ official rhetoric and
commitments to protect the development of their groups.
4 of 32
Like the country’s vague religious policy, China’s official statistics on religious communities are
described as ‘guesstimates at best and fabrications at worst’ (Yang 2006). To bridge this gap, in this
paper, I will provide an overview of contemporary China’s religious policies and communities based
on original cross-provincial data collected by myself and my colleagues in summer 2008. This paper
will test two mainstream theories and offers a new framework to explain why religious communities
develop better in some places than others. Sample selection methods and data collection processes
will be introduced and discussed along with the statistical results.
Ambiguous policy and statistics on the religious community in contemporary China
The development of religious communities in post-Cultural Revolution China is often described as a
‘revival’ (Wong 2001; Potter 2003). As Yang Fenggang (2006) describes, after completely banning
religion for a long period, ‘a limited number of Protestant and Catholic churches, Buddhist and Taoist
temples, and Islamic mosques’ were allowed to be re-established in China in 1979, when the country
had just started its new era of ‘reform and opening-up’. However, ever since then, China’s official
religious policy has been ambiguous. As mentioned previously, such ambiguity not only provides the
central government with considerable space to shape and explain its religious regulations but also
gives considerable flexibility to both local governments and religious communities to interpret the
official policy in ways most beneficial to them.
Three years after the 1979 reforms, the Central Government’s Document No.19 officially granted
legal status to five religions - Buddhism, Daoism, Islam, Protestantism, and Catholicism. The same
document, however, also restricted the activities of these groups, stating that they should only be
held by officially registered religious associations and personnel and within officially registered
religious sites (Yang 2004). Issued the same year, the new Constitution of the People’s Republic of
China also clearly indicates that the State protects religious freedom and ‘normal’ religious activities.
Considering the complete ban on religious organisations and practices during the Cultural Revolution,
it is not unfair to say that 1982 saw the Chinese Government greatly loosen its religious restrictions.
However, both Document No. 19 and the new Constitution only provide limited space for religious
5 of 32
activities: by ambiguously prescribing that ‘the State protects normal religious activities’3, the
Constitution actually provides the State (both at the central and local levels) with strong
discretionary powers regarding religious affairs, since only ‘normal’ religious activities are entitled to
enjoy the State’s protection and only the State can define which activities are ‘normal’. Similarly,
Article 12 of the Regulations on Religious Affairs of the People’s Republic China clearly states that
collective religious activities can only be ‘held in registered religious sites’, that these activities should
be ‘organised by registered religious bodies and presided over by religious personnel’, and that their
process shall be ‘in compliance with religious doctrines and canons’4. Many scholars, therefore,
argue that the State still tightly restricts religious affairs in China, particularly as only registered
groups of the five official religious (i.e. Buddhism, Daoism, Muslim, Catholicism and Protestantism)
are entitled to enjoy the State’s protection (Ashiwa & Wank 2007, pp.339-340; Spiegel 2004, p.43;
Kolodner 1994). Indeed, according to Potter (2003, p.320), the Chinese Government’s recognition of
the five official religions actually coincides with ‘an effort to exclude folk religions, superstition and
cults from the bounds of protection’. Some researchers even argue that China’s religious policy ‘aim[s]
at control not protection’ (Yang 2006, p.96; HRIC 2005).
Thanks to institutional ambiguity, while the state is able to flexibly formulate its attitude and actions
towards religious communities to satisfy its own interests, religious believers and groups are also
able to seek political opportunities from the same Constitution and laws. However, despite the fact
that ‘the [State’s] predominant view on religion has moved away from militant atheism to a more
scientific, objective and consequently more balanced approach to religion’ (Yang 2004), religion
remains a relatively under-researched field in contemporary China.
Official statistics on religious populations are usually considered rough and unreliable and are
updated infrequently (Hunter & Chan 1993, p.8). According to official sources, there are over 100
million religious believers, more than 100,000 religious sites, about 300,000 professional religious
3
The English translation of the Constitution of the People’s Republic of China (1982) is downloadable from the
Centre on Religion and Chinese Society at Purdue University
(https://www.purdue.edu/crcs/itemResources/PRCDoc/pdf/Constitution.pdf, [accessed Mar 5, 2012]).
4
The English translation of the Regulations on Religious Affairs of the People’s Republic China is downloadable from
the Centre on Religion and Chinese Society at Purdue University
(https://www.purdue.edu/crcs/itemResources/PRCDoc/pdf/Regulations_on_Religious_Affairs_no426.pdf, [accessed
Mar 5, 2012]).
6 of 32
personnel and over 3,000 religious associations in China today5. Considering the almost total absence
of religion during the ‘Cultural Revolution’, such figures are impressive. However, these numbers are
widely regarded as underestimates for several reasons. First, the official statistics only cover religious
believers and groups that are officially recognised and registered. Therefore, individual religious
practitioners and unofficial religious group members are likely to have been overlooked by the
official statistics. Second, despite increasing religious tolerance in China, religious groups are still
politically sensitive. Local officials may be regarded as lacking in governance capability if religious
communities with radical tendencies appear in their jurisdictions, and thus have an incentive not to
count unregistered religious groups. Even the head of China’s State Administration for Religious
Affairs once acknowledged that ‘the negative numbers come from the cadres; and the cadres come
from the negative numbers’ (Ye, 2000, p.9). Last but not least, local governments may also tolerate or
even encourage unregistered religious groups for economic reasons. According to Ashiwa and Wank
(2007, p.344), through putting religious sites into commercial use, local governments are able to
‘avoid the cost of maintaining religious sites’ and ‘increase tax revenue’. Considering the increasing
financial pressure on local governments, local officials are likely to take such opportunities when
conditions permit, and official religious statistics are likely to remain at the low end of the spectrum.
Outside of official statistics, many other efforts have been made to estimate the accurate scale of
religious communities in contemporary China, although there is hardly any agreement. For example,
The 1997 Britannica Book of the Year suggests that there were almost 221 million Chinese Folk
Religionists in China as early as 1996 (Daume 1997), representing about 18.06% of the national
population at the time. However, according to Lai (2005), a combination of official and unofficial data
from various sources suggested that there were almost 200 million religious believers in China in
2003, which is 15.48% of the then national population of 1.29 billion. Yang (2006) argues that there
were as many as 100 million official religious practitioners, 200 million illegal religious practitioners
and more than 300 million practitioners from religions with ambiguous legal status in China; in other
words, around 45.65% of the Chinese population were religious believers in 2006. Despite the huge
5
These figures can be found both on the official website of the central government of the People’s Republic of China
(‘Religious Believers’, https://english.gov.cn/2006-02/08/content_182603.htm, [accessed Feb 15, 2012]), and
china.org.cn (‘The Present Conditions of Religion in China’,
https://www.china.org.cn/living_in_china/abc/2009-06/29/content_18032670.htm, [accessed Feb 15, 2012]), which is
supervised by the information office of the State Council of the PRC.
7 of 32
data discrepancies, the aforementioned figures, together with many other researchers in the field,
have made reasonable contributions towards a more accurate and comprehensive understanding of
the actual size of the religious community in contemporary China. However, such estimates are rarely
based on large-scale and first-hand empirical data from China. The cross-provincial survey that my
colleagues and I conducted in summer 2008 provided a large amount of data on religious believers
and groups in contemporary rural China, which has enabled us to draw a relatively more accurate
estimation of the scale and distribution of religious communities in contemporary rural China.
Surveying Religious Communities in Contemporary Rural China
The huge variations among existing estimates of the religious population in China are mainly due to
different research scopes, measuring methods, and data resources. The statistical results presented
in this report are based on the second round of a regular cross-provincial survey scheme led and
supervised by scholars at the Center for Chinese Agricultural Policy and Peking University in Beijing.
As a questionnaire designer and survey instructor, I participated in both the pilot surveys and the
main survey in summer 2008.
The huge cultural, economic, social, and political variations among different regions of China meant
that simple random sampling was not considered an appropriate approach for our research (Bernard
1998, pp.149-152). My colleagues and I therefore divided China into six areas using conventional
socio-political boundaries, with each area housing a population with relatively similar cultural,
economic, and political conditions. Within each area, one sample province was randomly selected;
within each sample province, five sample counties were randomly selected; within each sample
county, two sample townships were randomly selected; and within each township, two sample
villages were randomly selected. Through this stratified quasi-random sampling approach, our design
sample scaled 120 villages. However, because two of the sample villages in Sichuan Province had
been seriously damaged by a major earthquake that killed around 80,000 people, these were
dropped from the final sample. One extra village in Jilin Province was included in the sample due to a
practical arrangement made during the first round of the survey in 2005, and this village was kept in
order to enable comparisons. The actual sample, therefore, contained 119 villages in total. Table 1
8 of 32
displays the descriptive statistics of these sample villages.
Table 1
Descriptive statistics of sampled villages
Province
Number
of
villages
sampled
Average
village
area
(mu) 6
Average
village
population
Average
number of
village
households
Average number
of natural
settlements within
each administrative
village
Average
village income
per capita
(yuan)
Average
village
labour force
rate (%)
Average
village
illiteracy
rate
(%)
Average
village
government
annual
income (yuan)
Average
village party
membership
Jiangsu
20
5629.40
2142.35
633.85
4.60
5856.45
50.49
4.43
1255448.00
51.45
Sichuan
18
5486.83
1535.33
428.78
12.35
3094.50
55.40
10.06
11198.33
34.61
Shaanxi
20
7493.30
880.55
214.05
2.20
2331.75
49.47
30.05
46230.00
22.15
Jilin
21
19586.95
1302.60
379.67
4.33
3811.57
46.97
3.95
289523.80
29.05
Hebei
20
2820.40
1264.30
310.70
1.05
2782.50
53.31
7.29
48817.50
26.95
Fujian
20
15475.15
2364.60
613.65
6.85
5415.40
55.19
7.49
656185.00
49.95
Total
119
9566.84
1580.05
429.71
5.04
3894.67
51.70
10.50
390043.50
35.65
As shown in Table 1, huge variations exist among the six sample provinces. Jilin has the largest average village area; Sichuan has the highest average number
of natural settlements in each administrative village; Jiangsu and Fujian villages are relatively high in population, household, government revenue, per capita
income, and party membership; and Shaanxi has the highest average village illiteracy rate. Such descriptive statistical results confirm that our approach of
dividing China into different regions prior to stratified random sampling was necessary as the representativeness of the sample could otherwise have been
6
Mu is a Chinese unit of area. 1 mu roughly equals to 0.165 acres.
9 of 32
compromised by the huge demographic, geographic, and socioeconomic differences between the regions.
Through interviewing village cadres and verifying official statistics in each sample village, our investigating team collected data on village demographics,
geography, economy and government capacities. Data on the history, structure and social function of rural religious communities in our sample villages was
also collected by inviting elites to complete special questionnaires. In addition, about twenty villagers in each sample village were randomly selected and
their basic personal information and religious faith were recorded through structured interviews. When the selected interviewee was not in the village at the
time of our survey, another randomly selected villager was chosen to replace them. Table 2 displays the descriptive statistics of sample villagers.
Table 2
Descriptive statistics of sampled villagers
Province
Number of
villages in
sample
Jiangsu
Sichuan
Shaanxi
Jilin
Hebei
Fujian
Total
400
376
398
406
398
400
2378
Average
number of
villagers in
each
village
20.0
20.9
19.3
19.3
19.9
20.0
20.0
Male
proportion
(%)
Average
age in
2008
(years)
Education
(years)
Agricultural
household
proportion
(%)
Party
member
proportion
(%)
Annual
family
income
(yuan)
Ethnic
minority
proportion
(%)
Married
population
proportion
(%)
67.2
59.6
61.8
60.3
58.8
71.8
63.3
51.61
53.71
48.57
48.17
50.25
48.61
50.11
6.62
5.44
5.64
6.97
6.33
6.15
6.20
97.0
94.7
95.7
96.6
97.0
96.5
96.3
15.8
14.1
8.8
10.1
12.8
14.2
12.6
33518
21738
21636
29796
20145
43280
28435
0.0
0.3
0.3
20.7
0.0
0.2
3.7
94.2
88.6
92.7
95.6
94.5
95.2
93.5
As shown in Table 2, sample villagers in Fujian and Jiangsu have relatively high household income, making the level of economic development of these two
provinces the highest among the sample provinces; this is consistent with the statistical results of the sample villages displayed in Table 1. Table 2 also shows
that most of our sample villages are married and from agricultural households. The average age and size of the married population in our sample villages is
10 of 32
higher than that of the national population, possibly because young and unmarried Chinese villagers
are more likely to become migrant workers and hence are less likely to be included in our survey. The
relatively high proportion of Party members in our sample data may reflect the fact that Party
members are more likely to stay in their own villages, since they may enjoy better opportunities
there than ordinary villagers. It should also be noted that, because our survey was conducted in June
and July, when male migrant workers are more likely to return home to join the summer harvest, this
may have increased the proportion of males in our survey. The ethnic minority population is
significantly higher in Jilin because of the inclusion of an autonomous prefecture of Korean Chinese;
however, apart from this, the ethnic minority proportion of our sample data is relatively low, as none
of the five Provincial-level Ethnic Autonomous Regions were selected during our sampling process. In
other words, although my colleagues and I tried our best to avoid bias throughout the entire process
of survey design and data collection, some bias remains. However, considering the socio-political
situation in contemporary China, much of this bias is unavoidable, if not inevitable, for such a
large-scale cross-provincial survey. Therefore, despite not being perfectly rigorous, the data collected
for our survey are reliable to a certain extent.
Table 3 shows data on the different religious believers in our sample. The proportions of each religion
as well as the general religious population are weighted by village population, which is highly
heterogeneous in our sample data as well as across the national population. According to our sample
data, about 46.59% of all surveyed villagers claim they have some sorts of religious faith. This
proportion is close to the estimation of Yang (2006). However, more than two-thirds of
self-proclaimed religious believers (or 31.09% of all sample villagers) do not or cannot clearly identify
their faith. Most of them regularly visit local temples or burn incense at home to pray for good
fortune. These people believe that there are supernatural powers that dominate or strongly
influence the fate of human beings, and they think their fates can be changed through offering
sacrifices to gods or ancestors. These beliefs and practices are often deeply rooted in traditional
Chinese cultures and customs of local communities; we thus categorise them as ‘local faith and/or
popular religious believers’. In addition, about 10.85% of sample villagers claim they believe in
Buddhism, 3.54% of sample villagers claim they believe in Protestantism, 0.71% claim they believe in
Daoism and 0.39% claim they believe in Catholicism. None of our sample villagers reports Islam as his
or her religious faith, which we believe to be reasonable. In China, Islam is closely associated with
certain minority ethnic groups, such as Hui, Uyghur, Kazakh, Dongxiang, and Kyrgyz (Gladney 2003).
Most of these minority ethnic groups are distributed in two provincial-level autonomous regions in
Northwest China which were not included in our survey. However, interestingly, one of the two Hui
11 of 32
villagers in our sample reported her religious faith as ‘local faith and/or popular religions’, and the
other described herself as irreligious. Such phenomena may reflect the fact that Islam is more likely
to be regarded as a set of manners for certain ethnic groups rather than a religion in China. The data
reported in Table 3 may not be fully representative due to the bias in our sample; however, despite
such limitations, our study of religious communities in contemporary rural China can still serve as a
reference for further research on estimating the accurate rural Chinese religious population.
Table 3
Characteristics of sampled religious believers and irreligious people
Male proportion (%)
Average age in 2008
(years)
Agricultural
household
proportion (%)
Ethnic minority
proportion (%)
Married population
proportion (%)
Party member
proportion (%)
Education (years)
Annual family
income (yuan)
Religious
Believers
Local faith
and/or popular
religious
believers
Buddhist
Protestant
Daoist
Catholic
Non-religious
People
Weighted proportion
(%)
Demographic, Political and Socioeconomics Characteristics
46.59
61.6
49.45
96.2
1.2
93.8
9.6
5.94
30816
31.09
64.8
46.46
96.4
1.1
94.6
9.8
5.94
29772
10.85
3.54
0.71
0.39
54.4
47.7
64.3
66.7
49.44
49.66
50.50
46.33
95.8
89.2
92.9
91.7
0.0
4.6
0.0
8.3
92.1
96.9
100.0
91.7
9.8
4.6
21.4
8.3
5.88
5.83
6.29
7.50
38911
24168
30630
46010
53.41
64.6
50.62
96.3
5.5
93.3
15.0
6.40
26448
Table 3 also reports important similarities and differences between characteristics of the religious
and non-religious population. The two groups seem similar with regard to proportions of agricultural
households and married population; however, compared with non-religious people, religious
believers appear to be richer, younger, less educated, less likely to be male, and less likely to be Party
members and ethnic minorities.
Mainstream religious development theories and the realities in rural China
The revival of religious communities in contemporary China not only sees new social and political
forces emerging in the world’s most populated country but also provides an ideal test ground for
mainstream religious development theories. As mentioned previously, the ten-year ‘Cultural
Revolution’ almost destroyed all religious communities in mainland China. As a result, the baseline
12 of 32
situation of religious communities in different parts of rural China was relatively similar in the late
1970s.7 Just three decades later, however, the development of religious communities is highly
heterogeneous in contemporary rural China. As reflected in our survey data, while the religious
participation rates of 10 sample villages are equal to or higher than 90%, in 13 sample villages they
are equal to or lower than 10%. Also, while there are more than ten religious sites in each of the six
most religious sample villages, four of the sample villages have no temple or church at all. Given the
same baseline situation, the uneven development of Chinese religious communities in the past three
decades has actually allowed us to observe and identify the key factors impacting religious growth in
rural China – and check whether they fit with mainstream theories – through cross-sectional
comparisons, which, thanks to our large-scale cross-provincial survey data, can be easily carried out
by ordinary least squares (OLS) regression models.
According to academic conventions, there are two competing strands of mainstream religious
development theories. These are secularisation theories (including the secularisation theory and its
two critical supplementary theories: the multi-dimensional secularisation theory and the pluralism
theory) and religious market theory.
Secularisation theory is rooted in the research of all three principal architects of modern social
science (Durkheim, Marx and Weber). Durkheim (1915, p.47) defines religion as ‘a unified system of
beliefs and practices relative to sacred things, that is to say, things set apart and forbidden – beliefs
and practices which unite into a single moral community called a Church, all those who adhere to
them’. Durkheim emphasises the important roles that religious communities play in forming social
solidarity, but he eventually follows Comte (1975) to regard religion as an imagined assemblage that
reflects facts in the real world. He therefore believes that, through the modernisation process,
science will gradually takeover the social role of religion, and religion will become a purely individual
issue.
Compared with Durkheim, Marx’s critiques towards religion are much more straightforward. He
clearly believes that ‘man makes religion, religion does not make man’ and ‘religion is the
7
It should be noted, however, that the hidden pattern of religiosity may have differed among Chinese villages even
during the ‘Cultural Revolution’. Evidence suggests that while religious activities were absent in many Chinese villages
during the Maoist Era, believers in some villages secretly persisted in worshipping God or local deities (for example,
see ‘The Chronicle of the Christianity Church in Wenzhou: Part 2’, https://www.wzjdj.cn/news1192.htm, [accessed Feb 15,
2012]). The impact of this hidden religious pattern on current religious development, however, can be controlled by
introducing a variable that reflects the religious situation prior to the forced secularisation in rural China. As shown in
Table 5, I include ‘number of religious sites in the village before 1949’ as such a control variable in my models. This
variable, however, is not significant in any of the three models, suggesting that the hidden pattern of religiosity in the
imperial era has had very limited impact on the distribution of religious communities in today’s China.
13 of 32
self-consciousness and self-feeling of man who has either not yet found himself or has already lost
himself again’ (Marx 1957, p.41). According to Marx (1975, p.395), ‘religion in itself is without
content, it owes its being not to heaven but to the earth, and with the abolition of distorted reality,
of which it is the theory, it will collapse of itself’. Marx’s radical critiques towards religion leave huge
space for even more radical interpretation. For example, in Lenin’s (1973, p.403) view, ‘Marxism has
always regarded all modern religions and churches, and each and every religious organisation, as
instruments of bourgeois reaction that serve to defend exploitation and to befuddle the working
class’.
Different from Durkheim and Marx, Weber systematically analyses the world’s main religions.
Through comparing the roles that different religious communities play in society, he argues that the
‘Protestant Ethic’ is the key reason that capitalism first emerges in Western Europe (Weber 2003) and
acknowledges that religions play important roles in modernisation. But he also introduces the
concept of ‘disenchantment’ to suggest that religious communities will lose their social influence
throughout the simultaneous processes of modernisation, rationalisation and secularisation (Weber
1993). In brief, despite their divergences on religion’s social roles and functions, Durkheim, Marx, and
Weber all agree that modernisation marginalises religious communities in the socio-political arena.
Such an assertion later becomes secularisation theory’s core argument.
Following Durkheim, Marx, and Weber, secularisation has been long and widely regarded as a
by-product of modernisation. As the leading figure of secularisation theory for several decades,
Berger (1970; 1990) argues that modernisation will first make religion give way to science in the
fields of art, literature and philosophy and then gradually separate social and cultural institutions
from moral and religious orders. Similarly, Luckmann (1967) and Wilson (1985) suggest that
traditional social orders that are associated with religions will be replaced by functional rationality in
modern societies; and Cox (1965) and Wallace (1966) claim that religious communities’ social and
political roles are challenged by urbanisation, pluralism and cultural differentiation, which are normal
considered modernisation’s ‘externalities’. In a nutshell, most secularisation theorists believe that
religious communities will be marginalised from the political arena in modern societies and will lose
their political influence.
Secularisation theory was able to dominate the field of religious studies for many decades because it
successfully interpreted the decline of traditional Christian churches in Western Europe. This theory,
however, fails to explain many interesting and important phenomena in the rest of the world. For
14 of 32
example, Weigel (2008) finds that the modern international regime actually provides the Roman
Catholic Church with a larger platform to influence the important international debates on
democracy, peace and human rights; and Bellah (1970) shows that religious communities have
significant impacts on public affairs in the United States, which is often regarded as ‘the most
modernised society’. Based on these and many other critiques, a new generation of religious
development theorists emerged in the 1980s and 1990s. These scholars also believe that
modernisation heavily impacts religious communities, but they argue that such impacts may not be
as simple as the previous secularisation theories suggested.
There are two strands of neo-secularisation theories. First, some scholars argue that secularisation
should be understood as a multi-dimensional concept and process, and they are thus usually
categorised as ‘multi-dimensional secularisation theorists’. Dobbelaere (1981; 1985; 1987), for
example, suggests that secularisation is driven by completely different and unrelated social,
institutional and individual mechanisms; thus the fate of religious communities in modern society is
complex and unpredictable. Similarly, Casanova (1994) argues that the secularisation process consists
of a range of social and institutional dynamics - including the separation of secular institutions and
moral orders, the reduction of religious believers, the declining participant rate in religious rituals,
and the individualisation of religious practices - and that these dynamics usually vary in intensity and
direction. Coincidently, Dekker and his colleagues (1997) demonstrate that individual religious
practices may increase in modern society, even if the general social impact of religious communities
declines.
Second, some scholars believe that the relationship between modernisation and secularisation varies
among different societies, and they are often labelled ‘pluralists’. For example, based on her
comparative empirical studies, Davie (1994; 2000; 2002) finds that traditional secularisation theory
can be successfully applied to Western Europe, but fails in the post-traditional United States, Latin
America, Sub-Sahara Africa, South Korea and the Philippines. She thus describes Western Europe as a
‘significant exceptional case’. Similarly, Hervieu-Léger (2001) suggests that, despite the general trend
in favour of secularisation, the actual dynamics of religious communities vary among societies with
different political and cultural institutions; such viewpoints are strongly supported by researchers
such as Kamali (2007), Spohn (2003) and Willaime (2006). Given the strong impact of pluralist theory
even Berger (1999), interestingly but perhaps not surprisingly, deviates from his previous position in
the late 1990s and clearly acknowledges that religious communities outside Western Europe are
actually growing alongside the modernisation process.
15 of 32
Religious market theory is often considered a relatively new approach (Giddens 2009); its roots,
however, can be traced back to The Wealth of Nations, in which Adam Smith suggests that a bishop’s
performance is related to the salary and social consensus that he receives (Smith 1976). Although
Smith never uses the concept ‘religious market’, as Anderson (1988) points out, he is one of the very
first scholars to believe that the development of religious communities is driven by the ‘invisible
hand’ – the relationship between supply and demand. Unfortunately, Smith’s approach was
neglected by students of religious development for centuries, and the recent wave of religious
market theory did not emerge until the 1970s, when Azzi and Ehrenberg (1975) created the first
production model of religious households. This suggests that (1) households with lower incomes are
more likely to have higher church attendance and (2) within each household, members with lower
personal income are more likely to have higher church attendance. Iannoccone (1998) later extended
Azzi and Ehrenberg’s model to suggest that religious conversions are more likely to occur in the early
stage of an individual’s life.
The most revolutionary religious market theorists emerged in the 1980s, when Stark and his
colleagues published a series of important works arguing, in the words of Giddens (2009), that
religious communities can be ‘fruitfully understood as organisations in competition with one another
for followers’ (Finke & Stark 1988; Finke & Stark 1989; Finke & Stark 1993; Moore 1994; Stark &
Bainbridge 1985; Stark & Bainbridge 1987). Mainly focusing on the supply-side of the religious
market, Stark and his colleagues argue that the overall level of religious involvement in modern
society is positively related to the intensity of competition among different religious communities
and negatively related to the intensity of government regulations (even if such regulations are
designed to increase or decrease the participant rate of certain religious communities). They believe
such an argument to be true for two reasons: (1) a religious community usually has higher motivation
to win followers when it faces the risk of being marginalised in competition against other religious
communities; (2) competition among different religious communities introduces a larger number of
‘religious products’ into the market that enable the fulfilment of members’ special demands. As a
result, participation in religious activities may increase.
Table 4 generalises the key explanatory factors, core arguments and representative scholars of the
two mainstream religious development theories. However, apart from a few exceptions, most
secularisation and religious market theories are drawn from observations and analyses based on
Western Europe and North America, despite the fundamental differences regarding the driving forces
16 of 32
of religious development. The external validity of these theories, therefore, needs to be
double-checked against social facts from the rest of the world. Transitional China can be considered
an ideal test ground thanks to its homogenous baseline situation and the current heterogeneous
situation of religious communities.
Table 4
Summarising the mainstream religious development theories
Theory
Key Explanatory
Factors
Traditional
Secularisation
Theory
Secularisation
Theories
Main Argument
Important
Scholars
Durkheim
Marx
Weber
Berger
Modernisation
Modernisation marginalised religious
communities.
Multi-dimensional
Secularisation
Theory
Modernisation
The impacts of modernisation on
different dimensions of secularisation
are complex and relatively
independent. The fate of religious
communities in modern society are
uncertain and unpredictable.
Dobbelaere
Casanova
Pluralism Theory
Modernisation,
geographic
location (and
the associated
social/cultural
structure)
Modernisation leads to the decline of
religious communities only in Western
Europe. Religious communities may
emerge or stay the same in other
modern societies.
Davie
Hervieu-Léger
Religious
competition,
governmental
religious
regulation
Religious development is positively
related to the intensity of religious
competition but negatively related to
the intensity of governmental religious
regulations (many such regulations
aim to protect or restrict certain
religious communities).
Stark
Finke
Bainbridge
Religious Market Theory
There is no operational hypothesis for either of the two mainstream religious development theories
that is generally acknowledged. However, considering the fact that the modernisation process in
post-Cultural-Revolution rural China is mainly driven by market-oriented economic reform, it is
reasonable to employ per capita GDP (a simple, reliable and well-accepted indicator of the intensity
of the market economy) to reflect the level of a village’s modernity. Therefore, in order to test the
secularisation theories, my first hypothesis is as follows:
H1: Other things being equal, the higher the per capita GDP in a Chinese village, the lower the
general religious participation rate may be.
17 of 32
Religious market theory suggests that religious development is related to both competition among
religious communities and regulation from the government. Considering that no religion is
preferentially protected by the Chinese state, intensive religious rivalry is likely to mean that different
religious communities are similarly sized. At the same time, the more intensive the rivalry, the more
religious the village community is likely to be. Defined as the ratio of the standard deviation to the
mean, the Variation Coefficient is a commonly-used normalised measure of dispersion of a
probability distribution; a higher Variation Coefficient means that the size of different religious
communities will be less equal and therefore competition between different communities is likely to
be less aggressive. Given the similar official religious regulations found throughout the Chinese
regions (not including the five provincial-level ethnic minority autonomy regions), religious market
theory can be simplified to the following operational hypothesis:
H2: Other things being equal, the larger the Variation Coefficient regarding the size of
different religious communities in a Chinese village, the lower the general religious
participation rate may be.
Three OLS regression models were created to test the aforementioned two hypotheses. For all
models, the dependent variable is the general religious participation rate while the control variables
include four geographic and demographic controls (per capita arable land, number of natural villages,
labour force rate and ethnic minority proportion), three political controls (Party membership density,
the proportion of village head and secretary’s salary that is subsidised by upper-level governments,
the village head and secretary’s average tenure of office) and three historical controls (the number of
deaths from the Suppressing Counterrevolutionaries Movement in the 1950s, the number of deaths
from the mass movements during the ‘Cultural Revolution’, the number of religious sites in the
village before 1949). The politics of county governments vary in different areas and may influence
the religious participant rate; therefore, to control this impact, county-level dummy variables were
also created as controls. Three models were implemented to test the hypotheses. The independent
variable is per capita GDP for Model 1 and the number of religious communities for Model 2. To
check the robustness of the findings, both aforementioned indicators are used as the independent
variables for Model 3.
As the statistical results in Table 5 suggest, neither per capita GDP nor the Variation Coefficient is
significant in any of the three regression models. In other words, other things been equal, the
general religious participation rate in Chinese villages is not significantly related to its level of
modernisation or the intensity of competition among different religious communities in the village. It
18 of 32
therefore seems that neither the secularisation theories nor the religious market theory are
applicable to contemporary rural China, and a new framework is needed before we can
comprehensively understand religious development in the world’s largest transitional society.
Table 5
Testing the Mainstream Religious Development Theories in Contemporary Rural China
General religious participation rate
Independent Variables
per capita GDP
Model 1
Model 2
Model 3
-0.0254
0.00000122
(0.11)
-0.0254
(-0.81)
(-0.80)
-0.0000886*
(-2.23)
0.00268
(0.92)
-0.00462
(-0.04)
0.0297
(0.17)
-0.0000880*
(-2.26)
0.00226
(0.78)
-0.0196
(-0.16)
0.0107
(0.06)
-0.0000873*
(-2.19)
0.00232
(0.79)
-0.0238
(-0.18)
0.00902
(0.05)
-0.926
(-0.61)
-0.129
(-1.70)
0.000197
(0.72)
-1.066
(-0.70)
-0.124
(-1.66)
0.000189
(0.70)
-1.056
(-0.69)
-0.122
(-1.59)
0.000189
(0.69)
0.0518
0.0535
(1.38)
0.0431
(1.32)
0.0437
(1.38)
-0.000799
(-0.07)
-
(1.37)
-0.000822
(-0.07)
-
0.00000135
(0.13)
Variation Coefficient of the size of different religious
communities
Geographic and Demographic Controls
per capita arable land
Number of natural villages
Labour force rate
Ethnic minority proportion
Political Controls
Party membership density
Salary subsidy proportion
Average tenure of office
Historical Controls
Number
of
deaths
from
the
Suppressing 0.0520
Counterrevolutionaries Movement in 1950s
(1.29)
Number of deaths from the mass movements during the 0.0401
‘Cultural Revolution’
(1.27)
Number of religious sites in the village before 1949
-0.00104
(-0.09)
County-level Dummy Variables
Constant
0.257
(1.33)
0.458*
(2.14)
0.477*
(2.14)
N
118
118
118
Adjusted R2
0.8185
0.8200
0.8177
t statistics in parentheses
* p < 0.05, ** p < 0.01, *** p < 0.001
19 of 32
Chinese local states as 'platforms of involuntary cooperation’
The main presupposition of H2 is that the intensity of religious restriction is homogenous in rural
China. This may seem reasonable on paper considering that, nominally, religious affairs in different
Chinese villages are regulated by the same central policies and very similar local administrative rules.
The reality, however, is very different. As Yang Fenggang (2006) points out, other than the few
religious communities that are officially permitted or banned, most religious ‘groups, individuals, and
activities [in contemporary China] fall in a grey area of religious regulation, which can be perceived as
both legal and illegal, or neither legal nor illegal’. In other words, the central government’s
ambiguous religious policies and regulations allow local states a certain level of flexibility in their
attitudes and actions towards local religious communities. Therefore, the actual intensity of religious
restriction could vary among different local states in rural China.
Existing research suggests that, compared with its local subordinates, the central government in
China is more suspicious of religious development and tends to restrict religious communities more
tightly. This is because such communities can be regarded as severe potential threats towards the
existing political order, in terms of ideology and in terms of organisation (Yang 2006, p.96; HRIC 2005).
The local states, at least some of them, are more likely to tolerate the development of religious
groups and are able to do so by simply denying the existence of such communities8. The underlying
rationales of local states are both political and economic. Politically speaking, local states are
different from the central government in that they are more likely to prefer short-term interests to
long-term interests (O’Brien & Li 2006; Cai 2010). Although local states may also see emerging
religious communities as threats towards the regime in the long-term, they are less likely to
proactively repress these communities; this is because such actions may lead to immediate
resistance which could negatively affect local government performance during their annual
assessments (Landry 2008). Economically speaking, local states may benefit from the development of
religious communities in two ways: on the one hand, the protection of religious communities and
sites may attract tourists and boost local financial income (Ashiwa & Wank 2007); on the other hand,
religious ceremonies may create temporary local markets and improve the local economy, which is
also a crucial assessment criterion of government performance (Gao 2006). However, a local state’s
tolerance towards religious communities is not unconditional. Actually, religious communities are
8
As both Pierre Landry (2008) and Cai Yongshun (2010) suggest, Chinese officials and cadres’ personal awareness of
a certain matter does not necessarily mean that the Government also ‘knows’ about such a matter. Thus, a religious
community in local China can easily be officially ‘denied’ when officials and cadres exclude its information from
official reports and proceedings. In fact, denying the existence of local religious communities is a widely-accepted
way of implementing religious policy in local China thanks to its low political and financial cost. As Yang Fenggang
(2006) suggested, this is the very reason that such a large ‘grey market’ of religions exists in China.
20 of 32
only welcomed when their potential contributions to a local state are large enough to offset the
political risks that they may bring. Therefore, the scale of religious communities in a Chinese local
state reflects the equilibrium between the local government’s motivation for tolerance and their
ability to withstand the central and higher-level governments’ pressure to implement strict religious
restrictions.
Since the end of the Cultural Revolution, China’s central government has exited from many fields, but
still controls the personnel system, propaganda, the People’s Liberation Army, and many monopoly
enterprises. Therefore, however autonomous local states may seem, they have no capacity to
compete with the central government in the aforementioned crucial fields (McGregor 2010).
Nevertheless, at least some local states enjoy more financial capability and autonomy in the Reform
Era than ever before, thanks to the land market and foreign investments (Dickson 2000; K. Tsai 2002;
Walder 1996) or due to the discretionary space that is created by a fragmented authoritarian regime
(Mertha 2009; 2011).
The de facto discretionary power of local states gives them the ability to tolerate and even encourage
the development of religious communities. Such tolerance and encouragement, however, certainly
does not come without conditions. According to conventional wisdom, the will of ordinary people to
develop religious communities is heard by politicians in democratic systems only because the fate of
these politicians is decided by their voters; such will, however, is likely to be denied and repressed by
authoritarian regimes which not only lack fair and effective elections but also strongly oppose any
potential challenges towards the existing social and political order. However, my field observations
and experience suggest that some local states in authoritarian contemporary China are still much
friendlier towards religious communities than others. As shall now be discussed, a local state is more
likely to compromise with religious communities when it happens to represent what I will refer to as
a ‘platform of involuntary cooperation’, a structure in which local state officials intend to maximise
their own power, but when their best option is to tolerate the development of local religious
communities despite the hostile attitudes of their superiors towards religious diversity.
A Chinese local state represents a ‘platform of involuntary cooperation’ when the officials in charge
of religious affairs are unlikely to be promoted but refuse to leave their position. Therefore, they
have the motivation and possibility of keeping their office on the one hand but face the risks of being
removed or replaced on the other. Due to China’s authoritarian personnel system, officials who do
not have close relationships with their superiors are less likely to be promoted and more likely to be
21 of 32
marginalised. I call these officials ‘stagnant cadres’. In the simplest scenario, there is only one
stagnant cadre who takes charge of religious affairs and this stagnant cadre has only one superior.
The superior has the capability to promote, demote, or redeploy the stagnant cadre, but his or her
own political career also depends on his or her performance regarding social stability, birth control,
economic development and many other criteria set by the central government in annual
performance assessments. The logic of the ‘platform of involuntary cooperation’ can thus be
explained as follows:
Firstly, like many existing theories in political science, including game theory, I assume that all
politicians (including the stagnant cadre and the superior) want to maximise their own power. In
other words, no politician has the intention to leave his or her current position unless he or she can
be promoted to a higher level.9 Since the stagnant cadre’s position is unstable due to the lack of a
close relationship with the superior, he or she faces a severe risk of being replaced by a competitor.
Therefore, to balance and limit the political threats from the superior, the stagnant cadre has to ally
with a third-party social force.
The ordinary people in the cadre’s precinct represent a possible ally for the stagnant cadre. However,
due to the lack of effective election, these ordinary people are unable to influence the political fate
of the superior unless they are organised into social forces that meet the following three conditions:
(a) they represent a social force that can be manipulated by the stagnant cadre, at least to a certain
extent; (b) they have the potential to launch collective action that may influence the superior’s
political career, such as collective petitioning, resistance, and demonstrations; and (c) they will not
disappear or collapse even if the stagnant cadre is removed or replaced. According to my
observations in rural China, many local religious communities qualify all three of these conditions:
they normally have close interaction with local officials who are in charge of religious affairs; they
have the capacity to launch collective resistance; and they remain active even if the local officials
who support them are removed or replaced. For a stagnant cadre, these religious groups are
undoubtedly ideal ‘involuntary cooperative allies’.
Forming an alliance with the involuntary cooperative allies allows a stagnant cadre to keep his or her
9
This basic assumption does not mean that I believe that all politicians are selfish. However, as long as politicians
want to achieve their ambitions – even if such ambitions aim to fulfill the interests of a society, social class, a certain
group of people, or just themselves – they must first of all keep their current position safe. Politicians who do not
insist on keeping their positions can hardly avoid being replaced by ambitious colleagues, even at the very beginning
of their political career. Therefore, most people we observe in the political system should meet the assumptions
made here.
22 of 32
position even when working under hostile superiors. Without the stagnant cadre, who works as a
buffer between the State and the maverick religious groups, the superior’s political career may
become risky when he or she intervenes in religious affairs. Religious communities have the potential
to launch collective resistance if they see their interests harmed, and such resistance may severely
undermine the superior’s political career. Therefore, even if the superior personally favours another
candidate, in order to secure his or her own political career, he or she is likely to keep the stagnant
cadre (who is able to ally with local religious communities) in their current position; and no matter
how a stagnant cadre may personally look upon religion, in order to maximise his or her political
survival, he or she is likely to tolerate, if not encourage, the development of religious communities. In
other words, religious communities are likely to develop better in those places where religious affairs
are charged by stagnant cadres.
A brief conclusion as the starting point for further research
Thanks to the reintroduction of religious freedom into China’s constitution, laws, and administrative
regulations following the radical atheist Cultural Revolution, China has seen a rapid revival in rural
religious communities over the past three decades. The statistical results of our large-scale
cross-provincial study show that the scale of this revival is much larger than what official figures and
many existing academic estimations have claimed, although, the extent of this revival is highly
heterogeneous across rural China. My statistical results suggest that both of the mainstream religious
development theories fail to explain why religious communities develop much better in some
Chinese villages than others, despite the same official regulations and restrictions.
Clearly, the development of religious communities in rural China is neither a solo sung by
modernisation nor a duet played by a monolithic state and religious communities. Instead, I suggest
that local states and stagnated cadres play important roles in shaping heterogeneous religious
development: on the one hand, local cadres (at least some of them) have the capacity to tolerate the
existence and development of religious communities because a fragmented regime and ambiguous
religious regulations allow them to enjoy considerable de facto discretionary powers in religious
affairs; on the other hand, local cadres (especially the stagnant cadres) have the motivation to
tolerate the existence and development of religious communities because they may use such
communities as ‘involuntary cooperative allies’ to balance and limit threats from their superiors. In
other words, I think the heterogeneous religious development in rural China is actually the result of a
grand ensemble which is concerted by religious communities, local states, and higher-level
governments.
23 of 32
In this paper, I have presented the underlying logic of involuntary cooperation between stagnant
cadres and local religious communities; such logic, however, remains a hypothesis until it is proved by
empirical data from contemporary rural China. To test the validity of such hypothesis, further
empirical studies in rural China are necessary.
Acknowledgement
I sincerely thank Professor Ran Tao and Mr. Xin Sun for their energetic support during data collection,
Dr. Patricia M. Thornton for her valuable comments and corrections on an earlier draft of this
working paper, and, especially, Professor Mingxing Liu for his crucial guidance throughout the
different stages of this research. Earlier drafts of this working paper were presented at The 24th
Annual Meeting of the Association of Chinese Political Studies and The 4th International Forum for
Contemporary Chinese Studies. I would also like to express my heartfelt gratitude to the organisers,
discussants, and participants of these conferences, especially Professor Vivienne Shue and Dr. Tyler
Rooker, for their incredibly helpful advice and suggestions. The remaining errors are, of course, my
own responsibility.
24 of 32
Bibliography
Anderson, G.M. 1988. Mr. Smith and the Preachers: The Economics of Religion in the Wealth of
Nations. The Journal of Political Economy, 96(5), pp.1066-1088.
Ashiwa, Y. & Wank, D.L. 2007. The Politics of a Reviving Buddhist Temple: State, Association, and
Religion in Southeast China. The Journal of Asian Studies, 65(02), pp.337–359.
Azzi, C. & Ehrenberg, R. 1975. Household Allocation of Time and Church Attendance. The Journal of
Political Economy, 83(1), pp.27-56.
Bellah, R. 1970. Beyond Belief: essays on religion in a post-traditional world, New York: Harper &
Row.
Berger, P. 1970. A Rumor of Angels : modern society and the rediscovery of the supernatural, Garden
City N.Y.: Anchor Books.
Berger, P. 1999. The Desecularization of the World : resurgent religion and world politics,
Washington D.C. ; Grand Rapids
Mich.: Ethics and Public Policy Center; W.B. Eerdmans Pub. Co.
Berger, P. 1990. The Sacred Canopy: elements of a sociological theory of religion, New York: Anchor
Books.
Bernard, H. 1998. Handbook of methods in cultural anthropology, Walnut Creek Calif.: AltaMira
Press.
Cai, Y. 2010. Collective resistance in China: why popular protests succeed or fail, Stanford, California:
Stanford University Press.
Cai, Y. 2005. State and Laid-Off Workers in Reform China: The Silence and Collective Action of the
Retrenched 1st ed., Routledge.
Cai, Y. 2002. The Resistance of Chinese Laid-Off Workers in the Reform Period. The China Quarterly,
170, pp.327-344.
25 of 32
Casanova, J. 1994. Public Religions in the Modern World, Chicago: University of Chicago Press.
Chung, J.H., Lai, H. & Xia, M. 2006. Mounting Challenges to Governance in China: Surveying
Collective Protestors, Religious Sects and Criminal Organizations. The China Journal, (56), pp.1-31.
Comte, A. 1975. Auguste Comte : the foundation of sociology, New York: Wiley.
Cox, H. 1965. The Secular City: secularization and urbanization in theological perspective, New York:
Macmillan.
Daume, D. (ed.) 1997. Britannica Book of the Year 1997, Chicago: Encyclopedia Britannica Inc.
Davie, G. 2002. Europe, the Exceptional Case : parameters of faith in the modern world, London:
Darton Longman & Todd.
Davie, G. 1994. Religion in Britain since 1945 : believing without belonging, Oxford; Cambridge
Mass.: Blackwell.
Davie, G. 2000. Religion in Modern Europe : a memory mutates, Oxford; New York: Oxford University
Press.
Dekker, G. Luidens, D. & Rice, R. 1997. Rethinking Secularization: reformed reactions to modernity,
Lanham: University Press of America.
Dickson, B.J. 2000. Cooptation and Corporatism in China: The Logic of Party Adaptation. Political
Science Quarterly, 115(4), pp.517-540.
Dobbelaere, K. 1985. Secularization Theories and Sociological Paradigms: A Reformulation of the
Private-Public Dichotomy and the Problem of Societal Integration. Sociological Analysis, 46(4),
pp.377-387.
Dobbelaere, K. 1981. Secularization : a multi-dimensional concept. Current Sociology, 29(2),
pp.1-216.
Dobbelaere, K. 1987. Some Trends in European Sociology of Religion: The secularization debate.
26 of 32
Sociological Analysis, 48(2), pp.107-137.
Durkheim, E. 1915. The Elementary Forms of Religious Life, London: George Allen and Unwin Ltd.
Finke, R. & Stark, R. 1989. Evaluating the Evidence: Religious Economies and Sacred Canopies.
American Sociological Review, 54(6), pp.1054-1056.
Finke, R. & Stark, R. 1988. Religious Economies and Sacred Canopies: Religious Mobilization in
American Cities, 1906. American Sociological Review, 53(1), pp.41-49.
Finke, R. & Stark, R. 1993. The Churching of America, 1776-1990: Winners and Losers in our Religious
Economy, New Brunswick, N.J: Rutgers University Press.
Gao, B. 2006. Yizuo bowuguan-miaoyu jianzhu de minzuzhi [An Ethnography of A Building Both as
Museum and Temple: On the double: naming method as arts of politics]. Shehuixue Yanjiu (Sociology
Studies), 20(1).
Giddens, A. 2009. Sociology 6th ed., Cambridge: Polity.
Gladney, D.C. 2003. Islam in China: Accommodation or Separatism? The China Quarterly, (174),
pp.451-467.
Hervieu-Léger, D. 2001. The Twofold Limit of the Notion of Secularization. In Peter Berger and the
Study of Religion. London: Routledge.
HRIC, 2005. Statement Provided by Human Rights in China on the Congressional-Executive
Commission on China’s roundtable conference. Congressional-Executive Commission on China of the
United States. Available at: https://www.cecc.gov/pages/roundtables/031405/HRIC.php [Accessed
March 16, 2010].
Hunter, A. & Chan, K.-K. 1993. Protestantism in Contemporary China, Cambridge: Cambridge
University Press.
Iannaccone, L.R. 1998. Introduction to the Economics of Religion. Journal of Economic Literature,
27 of 32
36(3), pp.1465-1495.
Kamali, M. 2007. Multiple Modernities and Islamism in Iran. Social Compass, 54(3), pp.373 -387.
Kolodner, E. 1994. Religious Rights in China: A Comparison of International Human Rights Law and
Chinese Domestic Legislation. Human Rights Quarterly, 16(3), pp.455-490.
Lai, H. 2005. The Religious Revival in China. The Copenhagen Journal of Asian Studies, 18(0),
pp.40-64.
Landry, P. 2008. Decentralized authoritarianism in China: the Communist Party’s control of local
elites in the post-Mao era, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
Lenin, V. 19738. The Attitude of the Workers’ Party to Religion. In Lenin Collected Works (Volume 15),
Moscow: Progress Publishers.
Luckmann, T. 1967. The Invisible Religion : the problem of religion in modern society, New York:
Macmillan.
Marx, K. 1957. Contribution to the Critique of Hegel's Philosophy of Right. In K. Marx and F. Engels on
Religion, Moscow: Foreign Languages Publishing House.
Marx, K. 1975. Letter from Marx to Arnold Ruge In Dresden. In Marx Engels Collected Works (Volume
1), Moscow: International Publishers.
McGregor, R. 2010. The Party: the secret world of China’s communist rulers 1st ed., New York NY:
Harper.
Mertha, A. 2011. China’s Water Warriors: Citizen Action and Policy Change, Cornell: Cornell
University Press.
Mertha, A. 2009. “Fragmented Authoritarianism 2.0”: Political Pluralization in the Chinese Policy
Process. The China Quarterly, 200, pp.995-1012.
28 of 32
Moore, R. 1994. Selling God : American religion in the marketplace of culture, New York: Oxford
University Press.
O’Brien, K. 1996. Rightful Resistance. World Politics, 49(1), pp.31-55.
O’Brien, K. & Li, L. 2005. Popular Contention and its Impact in Rural China. Comparative Political
Studies, 38(3), pp.235 -259.
O’Brien, K. & Li, L. 2006. Rightful resistance in rural China, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
O’Brien, K. & Li, L. 1995. The Politics of Lodging Complaints in Rural China. The China Quarterly, (143),
pp.756-783.
Potter, P.B. 2003. Belief in Control: Regulation of Religion in China. The China Quarterly, (174),
pp.317-337.
Smith, A. 1976. An Inquiry into the Nature and Causes of the Wealth of Nations., Oxford Angleterre:
Clarendon.
Spiegel, M. 2004. Control and Containment in the Reform Era. God and Caesar in China: Policy
Implications of Church–State Tensions, pp.40–57.
Spohn, W. 2003. Multiple Modernity, Nationalism and Religion: A Global Perspective. Current
Sociology, 51(3-4), pp.265 -286.
Stark, R. & Bainbridge, W. 1987. A Theory of Religion, New York: P. Lang.
Stark, R. & Bainbridge, W. 1985. The Future of Religion : secularization, revival, and cult formation,
Berkeley: University of California Press.
Tsai, K. 2002. Back-alley banking : private entrepreneurs in China, Ithaca: Cornell University Press.
Tsai, L.L. 2007. Accountability without democracy: solidary groups and public goods provision in rural
China, Cambridge: Cambridge University Press.
29 of 32
Walder, A. 1996. Markets and Inequality in Transitional Economies: Toward Testable Theories. The
American Journal of Sociology, 101(4), pp.1060-1073.
Wallace, A. 1966. Religion: an anthropological view, New York: Random House.
Weber, M. 2003. The Protestant Ethic and the Spirit of Capitalism, Mineola, N.Y.: Courier Dover
Publications.
Weber, M. 1993. The Sociology of Religion, Boston, Massachusetts: Beacon Press.
Weigel, G. 2008. Against the Grain: Christianity and democracy, war and peace, New York: Crossroad
Pub. Co.
Willaime, J.-P. 2006. Religion in Ultramodernity. In Theorising Religion: classical and contemporary
debates. Aldershot: Ashgate Publishing, Ltd.
Wilson, B. 1985. Secularization: The inherited model. In The Sacred in a Secular Age: : toward
revision in the scientific study of religion. Berkeley: University of California Press, pp 9–20.
Wong, B.L. 2001. Paper Tiger: An Examination of the International Religious Freedom Act’s Impact on
Christianity in China. Hastings International and Comparative Law Review, 24, pp.539-560.
Yang, F. 2004. Between Secularist Ideology and Desecularizing Reality: The Birth and Growth of
Religious Research in Communist China. Sociology of Religion, 65(2), pp.101 -119.
Yang, F. 2006. The Red, Black, and Gray Markets of Religion in China. The Sociological Quarterly,
47(1), pp.93–122.
Ye, X. 2000. Dangqian Woguo de Zongjiao Wenti - Guanyu Zongjiao Wu Xing de zai Tantao [Current
Issues of Religion in Our Country - A Reexamination of the Five Characteristicsof Religion]. In
Zhongguo Zongjiao Yanjiu Nianjian 1997-1998 [Chinese Religious Research Annual, 1997-1998],
Beijing: Religous Culture Press.
30 of 32
Ying, X. 2001. Da he yi min shang fang de gu shi [A Story of the Petitions of Big-River Immigrants],
Beijing: Sdxjoint Publishing Company.
31 of 32
ECRAN consortium partners: