See discussions, stats, and author profiles for this publication at: https://www.researchgate.net/publication/227267198
The Ecology of Entrepreneurship
Chapter · March 2006
DOI: 10.1007/0-387-23622-8_9
CITATIONS
READS
40
562
2 authors, including:
Glenn R. Carroll
Stanford University
142 PUBLICATIONS 10,528 CITATIONS
SEE PROFILE
Some of the authors of this publication are also working on these related projects:
"Authentic Kitsch?: Donn, Vic and the Emergence of the Tiki Bar Social Category" Glenn R
Carroll and Dennis Ray Wheaton View project
All in-text references underlined in blue are linked to publications on ResearchGate,
letting you access and read them immediately.
Available from: Glenn R. Carroll
Retrieved on: 18 October 2016
GLENN R. CARROLL AND OLGA M. KHESSINA
THE ECOLOGY OF ENTREPRENEURSHIP1
1. INTRODUCTION
Although entrepreneurship has been defined in many different ways, a common
definition ties it closely to the establishment of new organizations and their viability in
early years.2 By this view, the focal entrepreneurial event is the operational inception of a
new firm, and an entrepreneur is an individual who plays a central role in opening a new
firm. The associated entrepreneurial process consists of resource mobilization to facilitate
and sustain the opening event; it typically involves many individuals, agents and social
institutions, with a variety of interests. Accordingly, an entrepreneurial area or industry is
one characterized by high rates of new firm establishment.
Within organizational sociology, the most active line of theory and research
investigating the establishment of new organizations is commonly referred to as
organizational ecology (Hannan & Freeman, 1989). As is well known, organizational
ecology studies populations of organizations, focusing on how they change over time,
especially through demographic processes of selective replacement–organizational
founding, mortality, and growth. The major theory fragments of organizational ecology
predicting levels of new organizational establishments include density dependence,
structural inertia, niche width, resource partitioning and others (see Carroll & Hannan,
2000). Outsiders Pfeffer (1993) and Hargens (2000) view the perspective as exceptionally
cumulative for social science.
Despite the apparent relevance of organizational ecology, little theory and research in
the field of entrepreneurship uses it, builds on it, or even acknowledges its existence
through citations. For instance, we examined all articles in a recent year (2003) of issues
of the Journal of Business Venturing, the top specialized publication outlet in
entrepreneurship. Of the 43 articles published, a total of 2,225 other articles were cited in
the reference lists. Of these, only 59 (roughly 2.7%) cited organizational ecology articles
and books, loosely defined.3
It is not clear why entrepreneurship analysts commonly ignore the ecological body of
scientific work that might inform their efforts. We speculate that at least two different
reasons might be responsible.4 First, the discipline of sociology, within which
organizational ecology emerged, is not particularly concerned with applications,
especially those of a managerial nature. This is true of much ecology as well.5 Because of
the long time lag required for basic research to affect practice, it may therefore take
substantial periods6 for the practical implications of new developments in sociology to be
fully understood and appreciated in an applied domain such as entrepreneurship.7 Second,
organizational ecology theory typically casts predictions about new organizational
establishment at the population level of analysis: these arguments predict the rates of
founding expected in populations under various environmental conditions. Historically,
entrepreneurship has been examined as an individual-level phenomenon, with an
emphasis on rationality of action. Inferences about individual behavior from empirical
analysis of aggregated data can be misleading. Moreover, the types of theoretical
explanations offered for population-level processes may not be directly applicable to
individuals (see Aldrich & Wiedenmayer, 1993).
What this situation suggests to us is that organizational ecology likely requires some
translation before its relevance and applicability become apparent to entrepreneurship
theorists and researchers. Background conditions that induce or limit the propensity with
which individuals and others start new organizations will almost always be relevant to the
study of entrepreneurship. But both the abstract conceptualization of those conditions and
the aggregate level of empirical analysis common in ecology may leave implicit the
significance of theory and research for the individual level so engrained in the
entrepreneurship area. In our view, translations to the individual level are not necessarily
straightforward and may be open to multiple interpretations.
Population Founding
Founding
Attempts
Success in
Founding
Attempts
Organizational Mortality
Mortality in
New Organizations
Figure 1. Sequential processes involved in founding and success of new organizations
Given the ambiguity in deriving the implications of ecological studies to the level of
primary interest in the entrepreneurship area, one of our primary aims here is to ease this
task by offering a conceptual framework. The framework involves viewing new venture
success and failure as a process involving rates of event occurrence: a population
founding rate (decomposed into two constituent rates) and an individual organizational
mortality rate. Within this framework, the observable founding rate of a population is
depicted as the outcome of two underlying rates, each associated with a stage in the startup process. The first is the rate at which attempts at founding are initiated; the second is
the rate of success of those attempts. Success in this second process is associated with the
founding event itself and is to be distinguished from the success or failure of the
organization once founded, which is a separate issue involving the third rate in the
framework, the organizational mortality rate. The mortality rate is associated with
individual organizations in a population, given that they have been founded. As depicted
in Figure 1, new potential organizations travel down a sequential process, which involves
step-by-step winnowing of the number of units.
Organizational ecology provides theory and research about each of these pertinent
types of rates, as we review in greater depth below. Among other things, our translation
consists of sorting the various ecological arguments of founding rates into the two
underlying component processes. We also point to several findings from ecological
studies of organizational mortality that may potentially interest entrepreneurship scholars.
We then shift to examine key debates about the sources of variation in founding rates in
the ecological perspective. These include differences about the roles of: (1) macro vs.
task environments, (2) endogenous vs. exogenous processes, and (3) agglomeration vs.
differentiation. Finally, we identify a number of emerging research areas that present
interesting prospects for the future of ecological studies of foundings, and perhaps
entrepreneurship as well.
2. ECOLOGICAL VITAL RATES AND ENTERPRENEURSHIP
Most ecological theories of organizational foundings make predictions about the rate at
which new organizations will appear in a population under specified conditions. These
analyses take the organizational population as the unit of analysis for basic conceptual
and methodological reasons. In particular, to avoid endogenous sampling on the outcome,
the founding event must occur to some pre-existing unit, which is viewed as “at risk” to
experience the event. For many biological organisms, the female members of the species
(perhaps only those within a certain age range) are viewed as the risk set. Organizations,
however, do not have the requisite identifiable maternal unit around which to construct
such a set. Even using individuals or natural persons as the unit of risk falls short on this
dimension because they have multiple identities and can combine in numerous ways in
starting organizations, thus generating an uncountable number of potential units at risk
(see Hannan & Freeman, 1987).
In our view, a population's rate of founding can be usefully decomposed into two
underlying component rates. As Delacroix & Carroll (1983: 276) note:
The number of organizations founded in a given period will reflect both the level of
organizational attempts and the relative success of these attempts. Increasing either of these
factors will result in an increased number of foundings.
That is, organizational founding consists of two separate processes, a first about the rate
at which individuals are propelled to initiate actions that attempt to start new
organizations, and a second about the success of those attempts, in the sense that a firm
actually gets opened.
In a few cases, researchers have found social or legal contexts that allow them to
study these two processes more or less directly (Carroll & Hannan, 2000, Ch. 15;
Sørensen & Sorenson, 2003; Ruef Aldrich & Carter, 2003; Ruef, 2004; Jovanovic, 2004).
But in most cases, the only available information is on the actual founding events, which
represents a culmination of the operation of both processes.
Nonetheless, we maintain that the theoretical arguments that ecologists typically offer
to explain the overall founding rate commonly rely more heavily on one or the other
process, and ignore the second process. We believe that clarifying and classifying these
arguments will go some distance in making organizational ecology accessible to
entrepreneurship analysts. This is because, in conceptual terms, each of these constituent
processes seems easier and more straightforward to link to entrepreneurship theory and
research than the typical aggregate founding study.8 So, the first part of our review
consists of sorting the various ecological arguments of founding rates into these two
processes and pointing to some illustrative studies.
2.1. Rate of Founding and Its Component Parts
Decomposing the population’s founding rate into its component parts presents some
conceptual challenges but also serves to provide a clearer connection to theory typically
used in the study of entrepreneurship. The major conceptual challenge, about which there
is no consensus, entails specifying the activities associated with the event defining the
initiation of an organizing attempt. Abstractly, one can imagine the process beginning at
a variety of stages including idea formulation, development of a business plan, assembly
of human resources, capital acquisition, and the like.9
In the sparse empirical research on this process, investigators have adopted a practical
stance, using convenient unambiguous indicators that clearly precede any true founding
event. For instance, in studying potential automobile producers, Carroll and Hannan
(2000) use listing in an industry directory, legal incorporation or development of an
automobile (usually a prototype). For potential television broadcasters, Sørensen and
Sorenson (2003) use applications for television broadcasting permits. For heterogenous
potential entrepreneurs, Ruef et al. (2003) survey individuals to identify those actively
involved in the process of resource mobilization for a firm in which they held an
ownership stake.10 Ruef (2004) uses public announcements of the planned opening of
medical schools.
For present purposes, the major reason for decomposing the population’s founding
rate is that it allows us to understand ecological theory in light of ideas and arguments
common to the entrepreneurship area. To see this, first note again that most theory and
research in the entrepreneurship area is tied to the individual level of analysis. Recognize
also that the most commonly held theoretical model of individual entrepreneurs found in
the traditional literature assumes rational action and efficient markets. In its
unreconstructed form, this view holds that entrepreneurs are profit-seeking individuals
who make (basically) accurate cost-benefit calculations of the likelihood of success of
their planned enterprises and then behave accordingly.11 That is, an entrepreneur is
someone who sees a market opportunity when it appears, moves to take advantage of it,
and then reaps ample rewards after entering the market. Decisions and actions in this
view of the world are forward-looking: current behavior is explained as a result of future
expectations, which (in interpretations) are often assumed to be accurate (March, 1978).
March and Olsen (1989: 5-6) call the set of assumptions underlying this view “historical
efficiency,” because “institutions and behavior are thought to evolve through some sort of
efficient historical process” leading rapidly to a unique outcome.
In terms of the set of sequential component rates of the founding process described
above, the model of individual rational action under historical efficiency implies a tight
coupling of the two rates, meaning that the rates only move together in consistent
directions. Under strong historically efficient rationality, entrepreneurs attempt to enter
markets more often when they are likely to succeed in doing so and when their new
enterprises are more likely to succeed in competition with others (see related discussion
in Barnett, Swanson & Sorenson, 2003). These assumptions allow analysts to move back
and forth from empirical facts to theoretical interpretations with ease, and without regard
to causal directionality. For instance, an observed high founding rate implies that new
ventures are more likely to succeed (because future favorable outcomes were seen by the
many new entrepreneurs and these projections motivated them). It also implies higher
rates of initiation of organizing attempts (because more entrepreneurs saw the future
conditions and tried to enter) and success at founding attempts (the entrepreneurs who
tried to enter worked harder, and were more likely to secure resources from gatekeepers
and others who also came to see the future favorable conditions).
Ecological theory and research departs from the entrepreneurship tradition in two
ways. First, ecological theory operates at the population level of analysis. Second, and
more important from a conceptual viewpoint, ecology does not assume a tight coupling
between the two constituent parts of the founding rate. For instance, Hannan and Carroll
(1992) regard each of the population’s component founding rates as driven by
environmental selection processes. In their view of the world,
An empirically estimated organizational founding rate reflects both types of selection
processes, and these may work at cross-purposes. High rates of founding attempts can be
coupled with low rates of success in organizing and vice versa. The same observed level of
founding may be the result of very different environmental forces. Moreover, rationality may
characterize only one of the two portions of the founding process. That is, the apparent
rationality of a founding process may reflect the rationality of selection operating on random
founding attempts. (Hannan & Carroll, 1992: 199-200)
Note that their argument is not just about the mathematical possibility of rates diverging
but about the likelihood of social and economic environmental forces making them do so.
Hannan and Carroll (1992) go on to list a few factors that might drive one rate high while
carrying opposing implications for the other rate. For instance, involuntary
unemployment or forced retirement likely increases the likelihood of attempting to found
a new business but may not increase its odds of success. Conversely, a strong regulatory
regime may decrease the rate of attempts but increase the success rate of those that do.
The level of analysis difference between ecology and entrepreneurship is widely
recognized. But, we think that the abandoned assumption of tight coupling across the
constituent parts of the founding rate is not generally recognized–or at least its full
implications are not. We attribute this situation to a lack of complete conceptualization by
ecologists. In our view, in formulating predictions about population level founding rates,
most ecological theories rely primarily on arguments about either the rate of initiation of
attempts or the rate of success of those attempts but not both. The typical theoretical
argument discusses factors or processes affecting one component rate but not the other,
and then proceeds to derive a consistent population-level prediction. But, such a
derivation is only valid if the other, second, rate moves in the same direction, is neutral,
or, if opposing in its direction, exerts less force than the focal rate. That is, only with
some degree of coupling of the component rates does the usual population-level
prediction make logical sense when based on an inference from only one of the
components.
In fact, after reviewing empirical studies of foundings, we determined that reliance on
arguments about the rate of founding attempts is the most popular mode of theorizing
among organizational ecologists.12 For illustration, Table 1 provides classifications of
some selected studies that adopt this approach. More abstractly, we suggest that, as
currently developed, theories about foundings that focus on the following mechanisms
tend to use the rate of founding attempts: legitimation processes of various kinds
(Marrett, 1980; Hannan, 1984; Studer-Ellis, 1995; Hannan & Carroll, 1995) including
those associated with laws and regulations (Dobbin & Dowd, 1997; Wade, Swaminathan
& Saxon, 1998); freed organization-specific resources (Delacroix & Carroll, 1983),
including labor (Haveman & Cohen, 1994); collective action processes that increase
visibility, commitment, solidarity (Carroll & Swaminathan, 2000); and niche formation
(Swaminathan & Delacroix, 1991; Swaminathan, 1995).
But other ecological studies and theories about foundings do rely on arguments about
the success of founding attempts. Typically, these point to market or other environmental
conditions that should serve to increase the viability or fitness of a particular type of
organization, whose founding rate is then expected to increase. Table 1 also provides
some illustrative quotes of studies of this type. In terms of general mechanisms, we
suggest that, as currently developed, theories relying on the following tend to use the rate
of success: competition processes, including density (Hannan, 1984), niche width
(Dobrev, Kim & Hannan, 2001), niche overlap (Baum & Singh, 1994), and experience
distributions (Barnett & Sorenson, 2003); differentiation processes, including resource
partitioning (Carroll, 1985); collective action processes that provide support and defense
for a set of organizations (Hannan & Freeman, 1987); and trust engendered through
homophily (Ruef et al., 2003).
To make these theories and studies more useful to the entrepreneurship area, we
suggest that analysts should attempt to complete the conceptualization across the
sequence of rates and work through the implications at the individual level (for an
admirable example, see Ruef, 2004).13 While tight coupling of the component rates may
be the easiest and most straightforward way to accomplish this task, we personally doubt
that it is the most interesting and, ultimately, the most sociologically valid. Widely held
notions of bounded rationality suggest that while expectations about the future may guide
individual behavior, common social situations are filled with uncertainty, ambiguity and
imperfect information frequently, thereby making them tenuous at best.14 Much of the
recent literature on entrepreneurship builds on these notions in attempting to construct a
new model of entrepreneurship (see Ruef et al., 2003). If properly integrated, ecological
theories and studies might provide fresh ideas and evidence for the enterprise. For
instance, Ruef (2004) shows that entrepreneurial inertia, slowness in moving to the
operational stage of organization, may induce cycles in the evolution of the
organizational population.
Table 1. Illustrative arguments drawn from ecological studies of foundings
Arguments about the rate of attempts
Arguments about the success of attempts
Potential entrepreneurs react to signals, created by
previous failings, foundings, and new niches.
Delacroix, Swaminathan and Solt (1989)
Success in building a concrete organization depends
on the availability of resources, both human and
material…founding rates rise when the level of
resources rise… Hannan and Freeman (1987)
Organizational failings in the previous year may act
as a signal of a poor environment for league success
to entrepreneurs so as to slow the founding rate in the
subsequent year. Land et al. (1994)
Increasing concentration frees peripheral resources
that allow more foundings at the niche periphery.
Swaminathan (1995)
When ethnicity is highly salient, the niche for ethnic
organizations expands inducing members to build
ethic organizations. When society is polarized, it
becomes dangerous to erect and strengthen ethic
boundaries. West (1995)
Competitive relationships can be asymmetric, i.e.,
expansion in one population may legitimate the other,
but growth in the second may worsen the life chances
of the first by eroding its resource base. Lomi (1995a)
Potential founders will be more sensitive to local
variations in the levels of legitimation and
competition because of limits in their capacity to
collect information on non-local resource conditions
and because of the ambiguity involved in interpreting
events in more distant sites. Lomi (1995b)
Organization density initially opens opportunities for
protest and organization building, but later closes
them. Growing density of SMOS establish a resource
and institutional space facilitating mobilization by
other movements. Minkoff (1997)
Most new policies create constraints and incentives,
rather than dictating firm behavior, and managers
conduct new business strategies taking them into
account. Dobbin and Dowd (1997)
Cross-movement adoption of tactics entails intermovement competition, which in turn impedes a
movement’s ability to mobilize social support. Olzak
and Uhrig (2001)
State-level anti-alcohol prohibition frees resources…
entrepreneurs in neighboring states found breweries.
Breweries in the prohibition state also have an
incentive to shift their production to adjacent states.
Prohibition’s normative effect: entrepreneurs less
likely to found new breweries, because they fear
losing investments. Wade et al. (1998)
Foundings occur at a higher rate in industrial clusters
because in such areas entrepreneurs more likely obtain
the resources necessary for launching new firms.
Stuart and Sorenson (2003)
Entrepreneurial action occurs within a web of social
relations that both enable and constrain activity
…dense local concentrations of structurally
equivalent organizations increase the pool of
potential entrepreneurs in a region, thereby increasing
founding rates. Sorenson and Audia (2000)
Political instability leads to economic recession,
which in turn diminishes the willingness of
entrepreneurs to commit resources and invest capital,
given the uncertainty of future returns. Dobrev (2001)
2.2. Rate of Mortality (Success of New Ventures)
The entrepreneurship literature concerns itself not only with founding of new
organizations but also with their viability in early years. Within this tradition, ecological
studies are notable because of their comprehensiveness of coverage, often including
observations on all organizational members of an historical population (see Carroll &
Hannan, 2000). In our view, the ecological design provides a sounder basis for inference
about many questions of interest and sometimes leads to different findings.
For instance, it seems to us that most scholars of entrepreneurship assume that new
organizations are at a higher risk of failure than established firms (Venkataraman, 1997).
But a long tradition of ecological studies of historical populations now suggests that this
assumption is wrong. Specifically, two different streams of empirical research find that
new firms do not display higher mortality rates than that of established organizations.
One stream of research, concerned with modeling age-dependence, focuses on how
survival rates of firms change as they gain experience in a focal industry. The second
stream of research compares survival rates by entry mode, in particular, of new ventures
with those of pre-existing entrants from other industries.
2.2.1. Age Dependence
The key objective of research on age dependence in organizational mortality is to
understand how and why the viability of organizations changes as their tenure in a market
increases (for reviews see: Hannan, 1998; Carroll & Hannan, 2000; Carroll & Khessina,
2004). Initially, organizational ecologists took a position similar to that of students of
entrepreneurship: they assumed that newly founded organizations fail at a higher rate
than older firms (Carroll & Delacroix, 1982; Freeman, Carroll & Hannan, 1983). In terms
of modeling, this view implied organizational mortality rates with negative (or declining)
age dependence. Theoretical support for this belief originated with Stinchcombe (1965),
who argued that new organizations do not possess well-developed organizational routines
and employment structures and established relationships with environmental actors. As a
result, new firms are capable of only suboptimal operation and are at a high risk of
failure. Over time, however, as surviving new ventures develop organizational routines
and establish relationships with the environment, they operate more efficiently and their
mortality rates decrease. Evidence of this “liability of newness” is found in many early
empirical studies in ecology (Carroll & Delacroix, 1982; Freeman, Carroll & Hannan,
1983; Singh, Tucker & House, 1986; Olzak & West, 1991).
Beliefs about negative age-dependence were later amended in the light of new
theoretical and empirical developments. Some scholars propose that organizations might
be subject to a “liability of adolescence.” They argue that at the time of founding, firms
enjoy relatively low mortality rates, because they can draw from the initial resource
endowment. During the first months or years of operation, as the initial supply of
resources get exhausted, the mortality rates of new firms increase. Subsequently, failure
rates decrease, because in the process of aging, firms develop operational routines and
environmental positions (Carroll & Huo, 1987; Brüderl & Schüssler, 1990; Fichman and
Levinthal, 1991). Because mortality rates are still seen as declining over most of an
organization's life, this view is often regarded as a modification or refinement of the
negative age dependence pattern rather than a contradiction (Hannan, 1998).
A recent set of studies challenge the very idea of negative age dependence. They find
that organizations exhibit positive age dependence in mortality, meaning that older
organizations fail at a higher rate than young firms. In interpreting these findings,
scholars argue that as firms get older, they are more likely to deplete their resources and
become misaligned with the changing environment (i.e., experience a “liability of
obsolescence”), and develop dysfunctional capabilities, such as political coalitions and
the like (i.e., experience a “liability of senescence”). Positive age dependence has been
detected in a number of empirical studies, including especially those that control for the
time-varying effects of organizational size, something that previous studies did not
(Barron, West & Hannan, 1994; Hannan, 1998; Khessina, 2003).
2.2.2. Entry Mode
The second stream of ecological research that provides insight into understanding the
viability of new ventures examines entry mode. It explores how and why firms entering
an industry as new ventures (de novo firms) and those entering by diversification away
from another industry (de alio firms) differ in their survival chances.
Analysts typically assume that at the time of entry into the industry, start-ups and
diversifiers differ systematically in their initial resource endowments and prior
experiences. These differences, in turn, ought to create variations in organizational
survival (Bruderl & Schussler, 1990; Carroll, Bigelow, Seidel & Tsai, 1996; Freeman,
1990; Hannan, Carroll, Dobrev & Han, 1998; Mitchell, 1994). A basic prediction
contends that de alio firms enjoy significant advantages in survival, because at the time
of entry they possess more resources and greater experience than de novo firms.
The initial advantage of de alio firms has been documented in numerous empirical
studies, spanning industries, countries and historical periods. Specifically, it has been
shown that de alio firms exhibit significantly lower mortality rates than de novo firms in
the following populations: American labor unions (Hannan & Freeman, 1988), U.S.
semiconductor producers (Freeman, 1990; Barnett & Freeman, 2001), in the population
of new firms in West Germany (Bruderl, Preisendorfer & Ziegler, 1992), U.S. automobile
manufacturers (Rao, 1994; Carroll et al., 1996), facsimile transmission service
organizations in Manhattan (Baum, Korn & Kotha, 1995), British, French and German
automobile producers (Hannan et al., 1998; Dobrev et al., 2001), U.S. television receiver
manufacturers (Klepper & Simons, 2000), and U.S. computer companies (Swanson,
2002; Barnett et al., 2003).15
In studying the U.S. automobile industry, Carroll et al. (1996) elaborate on the basic
argument that de alio firms possess survival advantages. They reason that de novo firms
enjoy greater flexibility and that, over time, this fact shifts the comparative advantage to
de novo firms if the environment changes fast enough. Empirical studies in the U.S.
automobile industry (Carroll et al., 1996), in the British, French, and German automobile
industries (Hannan et al., 1998), and in the U.S. medical equipment industry (Mitchell,
1994), show, indeed, that while mortality rates of de novo firms were initially
significantly higher that those of de alio firms, the survival rates of de novo firms
converges with those of de alio firms as firms' tenure in the focal industry increases.
Despite the evidence about de novo and de alio firms’ differences in their
organizational outcomes, questions remain about the mechanisms driving them. In
addressing this deficiency, Khessina (2003) speculates about the relationships between
entry mode and innovative behavior, on the one hand, and entry mode and product
dynamics, on the other hand. She suggests that the greater flexibility of de novo firms
should allow them to innovate at a higher rate than de alio firms, but more developed
organizational competence should allow de alio firms to attain more beneficial product
outcomes.
Khessina's (2003) empirical analysis of product innovation rates in the worldwide
optical disk drive industry during the period of 1983 to 1999 confirms much of this
speculation. She finds that de novo firms did, in fact, innovate at a higher rate in their
products than de alio firms.16 De alio firms, however, display an advantage at product
dynamics: their products show longer market life and generate stronger competitive
pressures (Khessina, 2003; Khessina & Carroll, 2002). Given these countervailing
effects, it is not surprising that although de novo firms show higher failure rates than de
alio firms in this industry, the difference is not statistically significant. Otherwise, this
non-effect would be an odd result given the vast empirical evidence of the survival
advantages of de alio firms reviewed above (but see Banbury & Mitchell, 1995, for
another exception).
3. KEY DISTINCTIONS IN PROCESSES DRIVING FOUNDINGS
Ecologists approach the study of organizational foundings from a variety of viewpoints
and conceptual frameworks. Indeed, the difference around which we organized the
review of empirical studies in the above section represents one such background
conceptual variation, namely, whether theoretical arguments rest primarily on ideas about
the ease of launching founding attempts or on ideas about the likelihood that such efforts
will succeed in producing a founding. Another related conceptual difference lies in the
degree to which ecologists emphasize the causal importance of entrepreneurs'
assessments of market openings versus the facilitating role played by available resources
and institutional gatekeepers. For instance, the theory of resource partitioning (Carroll,
1985) predicts that market opportunities arise in certain environmental conditions and
that entrepreneurs will appear with organizations designed to exploit these opportunities;
by contrast, Halliday, Powell and Granfors (1987) argue that state associations should be
founded at higher rates in environments where organizational knowledge has
accumulated because founding costs will be lower.
In this section, we identify and discuss three additional conceptual or theoretical
differences in the ways ecologists typically seek to account for variations in foundings.
These are differences about the roles of: (1) macro vs. task environments, (2) endogenous
vs. exogenous processes, and (3) agglomeration vs. differentiation. It is our view, that
while an analyst’s position on one or more of these issues is frequently used as a point of
emphasis, the underlying theoretical differences are usually not investigated or
appreciated in their entirety. We think that theory and research would be improved if
these differences rose to the level of debate and spurred competitive empirical tests. At
the current moment, we know little about the relative importance of many of the detailed
effects documented in the literature.
3.1. Macro Environment vs. Task Environment
One difference in the ways ecologists analyze foundings involves the degree of
specificity (or proximity) conceptualized in environmental variables. Many studies
include variables measuring some aspect of the macro socio-economic environment (e.g.,
GNP, war-year dummies, depression-year dummies, collective violence), while others
include variables that impinge more directly on the focal population, variables that
organizational theorists sometimes refer to as part of the “task environment” (e.g.,
product market size, number of competitors, prices of supplies; prohibitions of various
kinds). In the typical study, both types of variables are included but the theoretical and
analytical focus lies almost exclusively with the task environment variables; the macro
environmental variables are treated as controls.
An interesting popular variable in this context is population age, a measure of the
time elapsed since the first appearance of an organization in the population. This variable
is often used in model specifications but it has been treated in various ways, as part of the
macro environment and as part of the task environment. While commonly regarded as a
control, population age has also been seen as reflective of some underlying process. For
instance, Halliday et al. (1987) suggests that population age reflects the accumulated
stock of organizational knowledge in a population. In the most developed theory, Hannan
(1997) argues that population age tracks population inertia, the process by which
organizational processes become structurally locked in and institutionalized.
Our view is that ecologists in general have been too casual in their treatments of the
macro environment, simply taking whatever data is handy and regarding macro variables
as providing controls so as to avoid interpretation. The problem is that while these
variables often show big effects, the effects often vary across studies and specifications;
inclusion or exclusion of these variables in a model often affects the findings for the
variables of primary theoretical interest. Accordingly, we suggest that research would be
improved if greater attention were paid to these specifications. We also suggest it would
improve the situation if researchers were expected to make substantive interpretations of
these effects, which could then be compared across studies. At least then anomalies could
be identified as such. Although it is a long way off, this approach might ultimately lead to
a conceptual framework for theory about the macro environment, something current
practice seems unlikely to generate.
3.2. Endogenous vs. Exogenous Processes
Perhaps the most active broad conceptual difference in the way ecological analysts
approach the study of organizational foundings concerns whether they focus on
endogenous or exogenous processes. Broadly defined, in this context endogenous
processes are those that involve the postures and interactions of the individual
entrepreneurs and organizations, while exogenous processes are those that involve
individual and organizational responses to extra-population agents and social
infrastructures, including the state, professional bodies and norms.
Within the endogenous approach, we would place processes of density dependence,
niche overlap, organizational differentiation and resource partitioning. Density
dependence theory holds that foundings decrease in high-density populations (Hannan,
1984). Whether this is because entrepreneurs avoid highly competitive settings and thus
attempt fewer foundings, or because their attempts are less likely to succeed, remains
unresolved.
Research on niche overlap looks at individual organizational niches and identifies
their points of intersection, as when, say, two banks target the same consumer market
with similar products within a geographic locale. Theory predicts that areas in the
population’s niche space with less overlap will experience higher numbers of foundings.
Arguments about organizational differentiation use very similar logic but extend it to
proximity in non-overlapping areas of the niche space. By this view, proximity in the
niche space indicates competition. Empirically, studies of agglomeration often analyze,
separately, one-dimensional continuous representations of niche space, say geographical
location or price.
Resource-partitioning theory holds that when large generalists dominate a market,
they cover a central position where most environmental resources are located, thereby
leaving open previously occupied space in the periphery of the market. Under such
conditions, specialist organizations are expected to be founded in the less competitive
periphery. This argument, like those of niche overlap theory and organizational
differentiation, assumes (at least implicitly) that aggregate entrepreneurial behavior is
strongly rational in the sense that highly competitive contexts will show fewer foundings
than less competitive ones.
None of these arguments, however, advances very specific characterizations about
individual entrepreneurial behavior, its motivations or its consequences, thus making
difficult the sort of conceptual links advocated above. Frequently, theorists explain their
predictions by resorting to implicit rational behavior. For instance, Hannan and Freeman
(1989: 132) claim that “Given a set of environmental conditions that set a carrying
capacity, the more abundant the competitors, the smaller will be the potential gains from
founding an organization at a given level of demand for products and services.” At other
times, as with Carroll and Swaminathan’s (2000) resource partitioning analysis of the
microbrewery movement, entrepreneurs appear to be passionately driven by social
movement-like goals. But, conceptually speaking, there should be no doubt that most
theories of competition leave plenty of room for a fully rational interpretation, whereby
individual entrepreneurs attempt more foundings when conditions are favorable and these
attempts are more likely to meet with success in the same conditions.
For exogenous processes, broad historical changes in the normative order of a
population are often well known at the time of study. Research that resorts to descriptions
of these broad sweeping changes, or interpretations of such based on historical time or
period effects, runs the risk of restating what seems obvious to those who know the
history. (e.g., Studer-Ellis’s, 1995, description of the evolution of women’s colleges). The
difficulty for empirical research lies with identifying specific environmental actions or
events that drive these processes. To accomplish this task, researchers often look to
governmental actions as well as those of professional bodies that lie within the
institutional domain.
In our view, there is no applicable general theory about how entrepreneurs react to
exogenous institutional and governmental changes in the environment. These studies
almost always base their predictions on a detailed understanding of how particular types
of entrepreneurs and organizations are likely to react to specific institutional
developments. Some of them make arguments about how newly available organizationspecific resources are likely to encourage or thwart entrepreneurs. For instance, Tucker,
Singh and Meinhard (1990) show that initiation of a governmental funding program for
social service in Canada (Opportunities for Youth) increases the rate of founding of
voluntary social services program; and, conversely, a subsequent funds reduction
program by the government (Provincial Restraint) lowers the founding rate. Likewise,
Swaminathan (1995) demonstrates that passage of a law allowing farm wineries to
operate under special rules leads to a higher founding rate of specialist wineries.
Similarly, Ingram and Inman (1996) show that development of a tourist park around
Niagara Falls (as a result of public investment) generates a higher hotel founding rate. In
a study of African-American protest organizations, Minkoff (1995) finds that the
availability of outside funding yields more new organizations.
Wade et al. (1998) offer a more subtle analysis in their study of the effects of statelevel prohibitions on brewery foundings. They argue that prohibitions in adjacent states
initially increase foundings in a focal state because consumers will seek products there;
however, as the number of adjacent states with prohibitions increases, the effect reverses
and dampens foundings because these developments reflect general normative changes
about alcohol.
Other studies of how exogenous processes affect foundings typically look at broad
governmental actions and trace their effects to particular populations. For instance,
Dobbin and Dowd (1997) document the ways in which federal pro-cartel and anti-trust
policies affected the founding rate of railroads; they also examined the effect of public
capitalization of corporations. Similarly, Studer-Ellis (1995) shows that passage of
women’s suffrage laws in the U.S. increased the founding rate of women’s colleges.
The best of these studies examines both specific and general institutional changes and
ties them to founding processes in subtle and unexpected ways. For instance, Simons and
Ingram (2002; 2004) show the complex ways that organizational foundings of the
ideologically charged (utopian socialist) kibbutz organizational form are affected by the
political environment of Israel–manifested in state establishment, political violence, size
of the Jewish population, and the densities of politically competitive organizations
(Moshav and capitalist corporations). They find that the kibbutz founding rate is
enhanced by the size of the Jewish population, and lowered by the density of the
ideologically oppositional capitalist organizational forms as well Moshav organizations.
They also find that the rate is usually lowered when the state takes on greater authority
(i.e., establishment of the state in Palestine and Israel). However, they also find that
political violence raises the founding rate, as does location in a politically contested
geographic region.
Whether looking at specific or broad exogenous changes, the underlying model of
individual entrepreneurial behavior used by institutional theorists is typically not well
specified; and arguments about, or implying, individual behavior are often incomplete
and inconsistent. Nonetheless, in our view, most of these arguments concern primarily
actions that facilitate attempts at foundings rather than the success of those attempts.
Enabling laws, public funds and resources, and norms about appropriate ways to organize
all likely affect entrepreneurial perceptions about opportunity. In fact, these actions may
over-stimulate such perceptions, leading to overly high numbers of organizing attempts,
and thus making success at founding less likely.
3.3. Agglomeration vs. Differentiation
The final conceptual distinction we consider is between those studies that posit forces of
agglomeration as driving organizational foundings as opposed to those that focus on
differentiation processes. When niche space is explicitly operationalized and
entrepreneurs are assumed to be rational and possessing accurate market knowledge, this
conceptual difference is clear and straightforward. For instance, Baum and Haveman
(1996) predict hotel foundings in Manhattan by assessing geographic positions on two
separate dimension of niche space: room price and hotel size. They find that hotels tend
to locate near similar hotels on the price dimension, thus showing agglomeration effects
(as entrepreneurs are assumed to benefit from spillovers in this situation), but avoid
similar hotels on the size dimension, thus showing differentiation tendencies (as
entrepreneurs are assumed to benefit from avoiding head-to-head competition on size).
With such assumptions and an explicit representation of niche space, empirical
analysis readily tells which force operated in producing an observed pattern of foundings.
It is much more challenging, however, to specify a priori which force will operate on a
given dimension and to explain why. It is also more complicated, but potentially more
interesting, if we do not assume rationality or accurate market knowledge on behalf of the
entrepreneurs. In other words, we need better theory about the conditions and
mechanisms behind the operation of agglomeration or differentiation.
In many ecological studies of foundings, the agglomeration/differentiation distinction
is only implicit, perhaps because only one or the other of the processes is entailed in the
main argument advanced. For instance, several empirical studies examine the role of
population niche overlap and non-overlap in generating foundings (Baum & Singh, 1994;
Baum & Oliver, 1996), with expectations that foundings will be more prevalent in areas
of non-overlap than those of overlap. Such an approach relies on the differentiation
principle and assumes that entrepreneurs are at least intendedly rational in avoiding direct
competition along the dimensions contained in the overlap measure.17 Similar
assumptions are implied, we suggest, in the usual predictions about foundings drawn
from theories of density dependence (competition component only, Hannan, 1986),
resource partitioning (Carroll, 1985), and Red Queen competition (Barnett & Sorenson,
2002), although in many of these cases the implied differentiation in the face of high
competition is not elsewhere within the population but in another population.
Studies that rely on an agglomeration logic also invoke a variety of specific
mechanisms including economic benefits that spillover (Baum & Haveman, 1996),
legitimation (Hannan & Carroll, 1992; Studer-Ellis, 1995), collective action (Carroll &
Swaminathan, 2000; Swaminathan & Wade, 2001), and social networks (Sorenson &
Audia, 2000). With the exception of spillover economic benefits, what is especially
interesting about these mechanisms is that they do not require assumptions about
entrepreneurial rationality or knowledge in order to operate. For instance, in discussing
how social networks operate to induce foundings in the footwear industry, Sorenson and
Audia (2000: 426) claim that, “…entrepreneurial action occurs within a web of social
relations that both enable and constrain activity…dense local concentrations of
structurally equivalent organizations increase the pool of entrepreneurs in a region,
thereby increasing founding rates.” Here there is no implication that these entrepreneurs
are individually rational or that they possess (or think they possess) any information
about what will lead to market success. Instead, they are propelled into action because of
the pressures and information that come to them by virtue of their location in the social
structure.
4. EMERGING RESEARCH AREAS
A number of new research questions concerning the founding rates of new ventures have
been addressed recently by organizational ecologists. Progress has been made in
understanding how entrepreneurs move from preproduction activities into production,
why established firms spin-off new ventures, how new venture formation is related to
niche position, what the dimensions of market niches are (with special emphasis on
identity), and how social movement-like behavior arises (how niches are socially
constructed).
4.1. Preproduction/Initial Organizing
Although many ecologists consider the founding of a new organization to be a result of a
sequential two-step process (as discussed above), very little is known about what happens
in between an organizing attempt and an actual founding. Many entrepreneurs manage to
mobilize initial resources, register their organizations, and even create a prototype of their
product or service, but do not yet deliver their products to the market. Ecologists and
others call such organizations and their organizers preproducers (Carroll & Hannan,
2000; Jovanivich, 2004) or preoperational entrants (Ruef, 2004). Recent research has
made some progress in understanding factors affecting the activities and fates of
preproducers.
Carroll and Hannan (2000) suggest that the rate at which entrepreneurs enter into the
preproduction depends on organizational density. Assuming that entrepreneurs react to
changes in the environment, preproduction attempts should increase during the
legitimation period of industry evolution (when resources abound, founding attempts
succeed and mortality rates are low) and decrease during the competition period (with
scarce resources, founding and survival prospects are dull). However, analysis of the U.S.
automobile industry reveals that the rate of initiation monotonically increases with the
density of either producers or preproducers (Carroll & Hannan, 2002). This pattern makes
sense if preproducers require only limited resources.
Another important question about preproducers concerns how they assemble human
resources. Ruef et al. (2003) proposed that the membership of preproducer teams likely
draws from preexisting social networks as well as ecological constraints on the
availability of others. Such recruitment processes will likely reflect homophily,
disproportionate similarity based on gender, family and ethnicity. In other words,
entrepreneurs are likely to recruit their team members among people they have strong ties
with (i.e., family, friends, and colleagues).
In studying organizational founding teams sampled from the U.S. population, Ruef et
al. (2003) found indeed that the composition of founding teams is primarily homophilydriven, along lines of gender, ethnicity and occupation. That is, founding teams are
composed disproportionately of persons of the same gender, ethnicity and occupation.
The drive toward homophily is so strong that it overcomes the necessity for (functional)
occupational diversity in entrepreneurial teams. The study also finds that social networks
strongly affect team composition, with team members being drawn disproportionately
from persons possessing strong social ties with other team members (strangers and those
with weak ties are not more likely to be included). Both findings suggest a theoretical
interpretation that entrepreneurs are more likely to rely on persons they are comfortable
with and trust rather than persons who might hold needed technical and other skills but
differ socially. Finally, the study also finds some weaker support for the notion of
ecological constraint, which holds that numerical minorities become disproportionately
isolated in the team composition process because of their relative lack of availability.
That is, numerical minorities are more likely to become solo entrepreneurs.18
Ruef (2004) also decomposes the entry process in analyzing the establishment rates of
medical schools in the U.S. He finds that the density of operational schools shows greater
impact on the entry rate than does total density (preoperational and operational schools)
because of social visibility, as with Carroll and Hannan's (2000) automobile
preproducers, Ruef also finds differences in founding rates by organizational form and by
rates of concurrent entry. Finally, Ruef finds that organizations with longer
preoperational tenures enjoy better survival chances. This last finding he interprets as
entrepreneurial inertia and shows that it can induce cycles in the size of organizational
population.
How long does it take preproducers to move into the production stage and start
shipping their products to the market? What determines the length of the transition from
preproduction to production? Schoonhoven, Eisenhardt and Lyman (1990) proposed that
entrepreneurs’ characteristics, as well as organizational and environmental factors affect
the transition time into production. The transition takes longer in industries with a high
level of technological change and in industries with intense competition. Ventures
founded by entrepreneurs with either relevant industry experience or experience of
starting ventures, or by former colleagues display a shorter transition time in the
semiconductor industry. Contrary to expectations, abundant financial resources slowed
this transition. Attributes of entrepreneurs did not have any significant effect.
Schoonhoven et al. (1990) assume that all preproducers sooner or later become
producers. Yet in the real world this transition may never occur. Carroll and Hannan
(2000) found that in the U.S. automobile industry during 1886 to 1982, only 11% of
3,845 preproducers were able to move to the production stage. What factors affect the
probability that a firm succeeds in becoming a full-fledged producer?
A firm’s successful movement from preproduction into production may depend on a
variety of factors. Hannan and Freeman (1989) propose that success in the transition
differs across organizational forms. For example, complex organizations (which are
difficult to build) likely spend more time in the preproduction stage and may never move
into the production. Hannan and Freeman further suggest that the probability of
successful transition may depend on a preproducer’s ability to understand the industrial
environment. The more difficult it is to predict the future, the less likely is the successful
transition from preproduction to production. Since the ability to forecast the future
declines with the length of the forecast period, firms that spend a long time in
preproduction are less likely to move into production. Carroll and Hannan (2000) find
partial support for this proposition when analyzing transitions from preproduction into
production in the U.S. automobile industry. They establish that the transition rate is
nonmonotonically related to the time a firm spent in preproduction. Specifically, the rate
of a preproducer’s transition into production is very low for the first half-year in
preproduction, then increases rapidly through year six, and then declines slowly. Carroll
and Hannan (2000) also find that the transition rate depends strongly on preproducer
density and weakly on producer density. The transition rate increases with increasing
preproducer density, at low densities, but decreases with increasing either producer or
preproducer density, at high densities.
Besides interest in the transition from preproduction to production, organizational
ecologists also study how preproduction activities affect organizational and industrial
evolution. Carroll and Hannan (2000) propose that the density of preproducers in the
industry has similar effects on legitimation and competition processes, and, therefore, on
organizational founding rates, as the density of producers. Specifically, at low densities,
an increasing number of organizing attempts should enhance the taken-for-granted status
of a population by facilitating recognition of the organizational form by society,
facilitating collective action by the populations’ members, and accelerating collective
learning about the form. At high densities, the preproducer density should increase
competition for the limited resources as the population reaches its carrying capacity. As
expected, these inverted U-shaped effects of preproducer density are found in a study of
American automobile producers (Carroll & Hannan, 2000). Moreover, these effects are
weaker than those of the producer density, because (it was speculated) preproducers have
lower social visibility than producers.
Not all new entrants go through preproduction activities before entering the industry.
Some new ventures start the production as soon as they collect resources (Carroll &
Hannan, 2000). Are there any differences between de novo entrants with and without
preproduction experience? Carroll et al. (1996) propose that preproduction activities may
help de novo firms build capabilities and accumulate resources before entering into
production. Consequently, de novo firms with preproduction experience should have
lower morality rates initially than those without such an experience. Firms with
preproduction experience, however, are likely to be more inertial. Therefore, as time
passes and the environment changes, the mortality rates of de novo firms with
preproduction experience may become higher than those of de novo organizations
without such an experience. Carroll et al. (1996) find empirical support for these
predictions, analyzing the American automobile industry.
Research on preproducers is still in its infant stage. There is a need for a better theory
explaining which firms are capable of making the transition from preproduction into
production and what the consequences of this transition are. Toward this end, the formal
model advanced by Jovanovic (2004) to explain waiting times between the preproducer
and producer stages should prove very influential.
4.2. Spin-offs
A central question of entrepreneurship research asks where the entrepreneurs come from,
and how their origins affect venture performance. Recent research in organizational
ecology makes contributions to the understanding of this issue by studying
entrepreneurial activities initiated by industry veterans (i.e., spin-offs). This research
explores a number of issues, such as what firms are likely to produce spin-offs, whether
spin-offs differ in their performance from other ventures, and what effects spin-offs have
on the performance of their parent companies.
Brittain and Freeman (1986) initiated ecological research on spin-offs. They
suggested that organizational differences predict the rate at which employees leave firms
to start their own businesses. When analyzing the semiconductor industry in the Silicon
Valley, they found that firms more likely generate entrepreneurs when they experience an
external shock, such as outside succession of chief executive or the recent acquisition of
the firm by a non-semiconductor firm. Firms with blocked career mobility, measured as
firms with low growth rates, show a higher rate (though the effect was weak) of spin-offs
as well. Employees working for generalist firms are more likely to start ventures,
allegedly because they are exposed to the variety of knowledge and skills at their parent
firms useful for starting ventures. More innovative firms also tend to generate more
entrepreneurs. Somewhat surprisingly, effects of the environment, including
organizational density, are weak and inconclusive.
Current research continues to focus on the factors that influence the rate at which
firms spawn spin-offs (see Klepper, 2001, for a review). Ecologists continue to make
contributions to understanding the issue of employees’ ventures by focusing not only on
the precedents but also on the consequences of spin-offs for both parental companies and
their progenies. For example, Philips (2002) suggests that industry veterans transfer both
routines and resources from their former companies to their ventures. Since transfer of
routines and resources help new ventures to survive through the first difficult years, the
greater this transfer, the higher survival rate of spin-offs. Parental companies, in turn,
may experience negative consequences from the lost resources and, as a result, suffer
worse performance and reduced survival chances when they generate spin-offs. Philips
(2002) finds support for these predictions analyzing Silicon Valley law firms (2001).
Another interesting finding of his study is that firms founded by people who left failing
law firms show lower survival chances than non-spin-offs.
4.3. Foundings by Niche Position within a Population
The success of new venture initiation and survival may depend on the specific resource
niche in which the venture is founded. Many industries consist of multiple potential
resource niches, and whereas some of these niches provide a fertile ground for new
ventures, others can be difficult to enter and survive in. In our view, work on resourcepartitioning theory has motivated interesting theoretical and empirical developments
about the founding rates of new ventures in different resource niches (Carroll, 1985; for a
review, see Carroll, Swaminathan & Dobrev, 2003).
As mentioned above, resource-partitioning theory proposes that (given specific
environmental and organizational conditions) when market concentration goes up, the
number of new venture foundings may paradoxically increase, whereas their mortality
rates decrease. This process is driven by the partitioning of the resource space, so that
different types of organizations operate successfully in different resource niches and do
not compete directly with each other. Large generalist organizations strive to occupy the
center of the market where they can exercise economies of scale. As competition
intensifies, weaker generalists exit. Winning generalists get larger but paradoxically they
leave some resource space on the industry periphery unused. Peripheral niches are not
very appealing to generalists because of the diseconomies of scale but are attractive
enough for small specialists. Since much of the peripheral space emerges as market
concentration increases, greater numbers of smaller firms can successfully enter the
growing peripheral niches. Therefore, industries that experience resource partitioning
provide fertile ground for founding new ventures.
By entering and filling peripheral niches, new ventures may expand these niches and
eventually render them quite attractive in terms of economic returns. As a result,
peripheral niches that were not appealing in the past may become attractive in the present
to generalist organizations. For example, the brewing industry in the 1980s was
dominated by a handful of large mass producers that made few varieties of generic beer.
Then small brewers came into play by producing high-quality specialty beer. Although
the market for the specialty beer was initially very small, it grew large and eventually
attracted the attention of mass producers (Carroll & Swaminathan, 2000). However,
despite later active attempts, generalists were not able to occupy these new niches.
Resource-partitioning theory describes several mechanisms explaining why even when
peripheral niches become attractive, generalist producers cannot enter them, whereas
entrepreneurs have a substantial advantage over established firms both in terms of entry
and survival.
One mechanism is authenticity of an organizational form that a firm embodies.
Carroll and Swaminathan (2000) propose that in order for a firm to be approved by
external observers, it has to offer products or services that are authentic to its
organizational form or identity. In the study of the U.S. brewing industry, Carroll and
Swaminathan identify four different organizational forms: large mass producers,
microbrewers, brewpubs and contract brewers. Microbrewers and brewpubs produce and
sell high-quality specialty beer, usually on the production site. Their organizations
resemble 19th century craft-like production firms and their consumers respond to an antimass production sentiment. Although specialist brewers began on the market periphery,
over time they built an attractive, expanding market niche. When mass producers tried to
move into this niche, they failed because customers perceived their product as inauthentic
and refused to buy it. It is interesting that although contract brewers are also specialists
they did not hold the same form identity as microbrewers and brewpubs, because they
sell specialty beer they did not make themselves. The illusory identity of a specialist firm
helps contract brewers succeed better than mass producers in the midst of the anti-mass
production sentiment, but they did not perform as well as either microbrewers or
brewpubs.
Another mechanism that may prevent generalists from occupying profitable
peripheral niches is service customization. For example, in the Dutch audit industry, large
generalists can provide service to any firm. However, many small client firms prefer to
deal with small specialized audit organizations, because the latter are more willing to
cater to their specific (changing) needs (Boone, Carroll & van Witteloostuijn, 2002).
Among Silicon Valley law firms, small specialist law firms are preferred by many clients
to large generalists, because specialist firms provide personalized service whereas
generalists firm are not willing to be so accommodating to small clients (Jaffee, 2002).
New ventures may also have a higher founding rate in markets that are partitioned
based on conspicuous status consumption. In industries where environmental uncertainty
is low, small specialist organizations may achieve high status, which generalists cannot
replicate by the nature of being big and unfocused. For example, conspicuous status
consumption is clearly observed in the California wine industry where only small
specialist wineries are perceived as “boutique”, “chateau”, and “farm wineries”
(Swaminathan, 1995). These wineries are associated with production of a wide variety of
low-volume, high-value-added products that are appreciated by customers who consider
wine consumption as a sign of status. Such customers avoid buying similar wine from
mass-production wineries, because mass producers do not posses high status. When
environmental uncertainty is high, however, consumers are likely to attach high status to
generalist firms, as occurred in investment banking (Park & Podolny, 2000). Generalists
with high status are very unlikely to enter low status niches even if profitable, because
this action can damage their prestige (Podolny, 1993). Thus, in markets partitioned along
a status dimension, small firms do not directly compete with large ones. Therefore, new
ventures can be successfully founded in niches with an appropriate status.
Resource space can be partitioned by geography. Geographic areas not attractive to
generalists may provide a fertile ground for founding new firms (Lomi, 1995a, 1995b).
Moreover, geographic co-location near other organizations of either similar or
complementary forms may prove attractive (Sorenson & Stuart, 2001; Stuart & Sorenson,
2003).
Finally, the resource space can be partitioned along technological dimensions. Recent
research suggests that new ventures are more likely to be founded and to survive in
certain technological niches. Khessina (2003) proposes that de novo firms do better than
de alio firms in niches at the technological frontier. Such differentiation happens because
de novo firms possess greater flexibility in their internal routines and their relationship
with the environment that allows them to be more innovative than de alio firms. She finds
empirical support for this idea while analyzing product innovations in the worldwide
optical disk drive industry. Interestingly, she did not find that de novo firms have a higher
failure rate than de alio firms; she attributes this finding to the importance of innovation
in this industry and the superiority of de novo firms at innovation. Khessina and Carroll
(2002) pursue this idea further by looking at product demography to understand the
technological niches that firms compete in. It turns out that new ventures generally
compete at the high end of technology, whereas preexisting firms are evenly spread out.
4.4. Identity Space as a Resource
Success of founding a new venture depends not only on physical resources but also on
socially constructed resources. Specifically, venture formation may be affected by the
ecology of organizational form identities.
Industries usually host more than one organizational form. For instance, the brewing
industry consists of mass producers, microbrewers, brewpubs, and contract brewers
(Carroll & Swaminathan 2000). Organizational forms can be distinguished by the
identities attached to them. Identity is a system of descriptive and prescriptive codes that
connote cognitive recognition and imperative standing (Pólos, Hannan & Carroll, 2002).
Identity delineates the magnitude of actions that a firm may undertake without violating
expectations of its audiences. For example, consumers expect specialty beer to be brewed
by traditional hand crafted methods. Therefore, it is not surprising that consumers
perceive specialty beer as authentic only if it is made and sold by microbrewers and
brewpubs but not by mass producers and contract brewers. On the other hand, consumers
who prefer generic beer are likely to buy such from mass producers. The example of the
brewing industry shows that identity is an important resource and the industry is usually
partitioned into different identity spaces. Entrepreneurs are more likely to succeed in their
attempts to found firms when they choose an appropriate identity for their ventures.
Ruef (2000) conducted a broader study examining how new organizational forms
emerge in the health care sector of the U.S. Between 1965 and 1994, he counts 19 new
forms emerging, complementing a pre-existing set of 29 forms. Ruef's (2000) analysis
focuses on the emergence of these 19 new forms as social identities. In particular, he
develops testable arguments about form emergence, drawing from institutional
(regulatory acts and government funding) and ecological (density dependence,
competition, symbiosis, and punctuated equilibrium) theories of organization as well as
social movement analysis.
Analyzing texts drawn from over one thousand journals and other publications,
targeted to disparate kinds of participants in the health care sector, Ruef constructed an
identity space within which forms might emerge. The dependent variable for the
empirical analysis consisted of the counts of the forms appearing in each cell of the
identity space. The study finds that new form emergence depends on the positions of
existing form identities in the sector, and by the density and size of organizations
matching those identities. The density and size of organizations possessing a form
increases the rate of new form emergence up to a point, at which point the rate declines.
The curvilinear relationship is interpreted as reflecting legitimation initially (in the rising
phase) and the competition due to saturation (in the downward phase).
Identity of an organizational form does not need to be based only on product
characteristics. Baron (2004) proposes that identity can also be defined by the labor
relationships prevalent in a given market. Labor market identity indicates what kind of
employment relationships are considered acceptable. Baron contends that although each
organizational form embodies both product-based identity and labor-based identity, one
or another can be more salient to the audience. Labor market identity may dominate when
employment relationships and human or social capital are of paramount importance.
Therefore, entrepreneurs who think about founding a firm might focus simultaneously on
both market-based and product-based identities.
Issues of organizational form and identity are of paramount importance in emerging
industries. New industries lack legitimation. One reason for the lack of legitimation is an
undeveloped organizational form on which the industry activity is based. When the
organizational form is underdeveloped, it does not generate a legitimate signal and, as a
result, the industry fails to attract resources and institutional approval.
Organizational ecologists propose that an organizational form is more likely to
develop and acquire a legitimate status with increasing density of organizations that
embody this form. Furthermore, the process of organizational form development is
facilitated and accelerated when firms that enter a new industry have focused identities
(McKendrick & Carroll, 2002). New ventures play an especially important role in this
process. In general, de novo firms should have more focused identities than de alio firms.
This is because de novo firms are typically founded with a goal of operation in the focal
industry and, therefore, their activity is focused on one type of business. In contrast, de
alio firms likely participate in multiple industries (or did so previously, creating a legacy)
and project multiple identities associated with these industries. While de novo firms
would be quite visible to an audience in the focal industry, de alio firms in the focal
industry may not be perceived so readily at all (especially if de alio firms derive the bulk
of their revenues from other industries). As a result, a simple increase in the numbers of
de alio firms may not contribute to increasing legitimation and institutionalization of a
new organizational form.
In an analysis of founding and survival rates of disk array producers, McKendrick,
Jaffee, Carroll and Khessina (2003) find empirical support for these arguments. They find
that density of de novo firms (but not that of de alio firms) has a legitimating effect on the
industry by increasing founding rates of all firms and decreasing failure rates of all firms.
They also find that geographically clustered firms, especially geographically clustered de
novo firms, have a beneficial effect on industry dynamics. This too is interpreted as a
consequence of perceived focus in organizational identities.
4.5. Social Movement-Like Behavior
Organizational ecologists sometimes explore how entrepreneurs in certain industries
undertake collective action to reach and persuade audiences of their worth. Founders of
new ventures undertake different collective action strategies to promote the awareness of
their activities. They establish industry associations (McKendrick et al., 2003), they
organize advertising campaigns in the form of competitions, races (Rao, 1994; Hannan,
Carroll, Dundon & Torres, 1995), conferences and rallies (Carroll & Swaminathan, 2000)
and they try to reach and educate the market in many other ways (Swaminathan & Wade,
2001).
Such collectively oriented behavior of entrepreneurs often resembles that of social
movements (Carroll, 1997; Swaminathan & Wade, 2001). The analogy is potentially
important for theory development because social movements and their leaders often defy
(or least suggest arguments alternatives to) rational action interpretations (Tilly, 1978).
This means that the collective action aspects of entrepreneurship may provide some clues
as to how to decouple the two component rates of the founding process discussed above
without assuming rationality.
Although the tendency of founders to organize collectively in new industries (or in
new market segments) is well documented, no compelling theoretical model has yet been
advanced to analyze the patterns of these activities in this way. The density dependence
model has been applied to analyses of vital rates of social movement organizations
(Olzak, 1989; Olzak & West, 1991; West, 1995; Minkoff, 1997). However, this model
does not really predict what types of collective action are undertaken by organizations or
entrepreneurs in different industries and why. A more explicit model of collective action
by entrepreneurs has yet to be proposed despite its allure and apparent promise.
Table 2. Key references among ecological studies of foundings
Theoretical contributions
Methodological contributions
Hannan (1984). Advances theory of densitydependent legitimation and competition.
Predicts foundings will show an inverted Ushape relation with organizational density.
Hannan and Freeman (1987). Proposes
modeling foundings as arrivals in a stochastic
process. Parameterizes covariates' effects on rate
of arrival using Poisson regression.
Carroll (1985). Advances theory of resource
partitioning. Predicts foundings of specialist
organizations will increase with market
concentration.
Barron (1992). Identifies estimation problem
created by overdispersion in count data on
foundings. Proposes negative binomial model
(possibly with autocorrelation) as solution.
Tucker et al. (1990). Accounts for foundings of
voluntary social service organizations in terms
of governmental policy changes.
Lomi
(1995b).
Models
unobserved
heterogeneity in spatially defined founding
processes.
Baum and Singh (1994). Founding rates
explained as a consequence of differentiation
using concepts of niche overlap.
Ruef (2000). Provides methodology for
inferring organizational form identities from
textual sources.
Hannan et al. (1995). Extends model of densitydependent legitimation and competition to
allow global competition and local competition.
Ruef (2002). Advances structural event analysis
to model demographic composition of
entrepreneurial teams.
Baum and Haveman (1997). Highlights the
tension between processes of agglomeration
and differentiation in driving foundings.
McKendrick et al. (2003). Examines a possibly
emergent organizational form by choosing a less
than institutionalized case to study.
Dobbin and Dowd (1997). Explains railroad
foundings as consequence of public policy
changes.
Wade et al. (1998). Analyzes unintended
effects of state-level prohibitions in brewery
foundings of neighboring states.
Sorenson and Audia (2000). Proposes social
network explanation for regional concentrations
of foundings.
Ruef (2000). Conceives of foundings within
identity space of organizational forms in a
community.
Swaminathan and Wade (2001). Draws
inferences about foundings using social
movement theory and research.
5. CONCLUSION
Entrepreneurship and ecology are both huge research areas with very large literatures of
theory and research. Given a common strong interest in organizational foundings and the
success of newly founded organizations, it is striking how unconnected the two literatures
are at present. While possibly understandable, this disjuncture seems to us to be
counterproductive. Accordingly, our review here has tried to provide motivation as well
as accessible conceptual linkages to ecology for those in the entrepreneurship area. Along
the way, we have offered comments on the ecological ways of doing theory and research
that might be of interest to those from that tradition.
6. NOTES
1
We appreciate the helpful comments of Olav Sorenson, Bill Barnett and Mike Hannan on an earlier draft.
Other common definitions associate entrepreneurship with innovativeness, with passionate motivation or with
organizational change. The perspectives behind these definitions are beyond the scope of this chapter,
although other chapters in this book do consider them at length.
3
We used our extensive knowledge of the organizational ecology literature to identify the articles and books
used in making this calculation.
4
We reject the notion that these analysts might not be aware of organizational ecology as generally implausible.
The journals for organizational theory and entrepreneurship do overlap.
5
Compared to the “entry decision” of economics, the ecological appellation of “foundings” commonly used in
studies of organizational births or entries into markets suggests less volition and more detachment.
6
In the physical sciences, the time lag for basic research to affect practice has been estimated at 75 years.
7
If this proposal seems unrealistic, then consider how long industrial economics existed as a discipline before
its translation by Porter (1980) created a foundation for the applied field of strategic management.
8
It is common these days to regard the micro level processes as more fundamental than the macro level.
Hannan (1992) provides a compelling counter argument, however. Citing the case of Darwin and genetics,
he argues that a robust macro theory is important.
9
Note that the challenge of creating a widely agreed upon conceptual definition of the activities defining this
event should not be seen as unusual or especially debilitating to theory or research. Indeed, a similar lack of
consensus about what exactly constitutes an organizational founding can be found in the earlier ecological
literature, and remains a slightly unsettled issue today. As long as researchers define and clearly
operationalize their concepts, research can continue to progress and be compared.
10
Specifically, Ruef et al. (2003) asked two questions to randomly selected interviewees: (1) Are you, alone or
with others, now trying to start a business? (2) Are you, alone or with others, now starting a new business
or new venture with your employer? If respondents answered affirmatively to either question, they were
asked two additional questions to ascertain that (1) they were actively involved and (2) they held an
ownership stake. Affirmative answers to both of these later questions were required to be considered a
nascent entrepreneur.
2
11
Of course, the assumptions of strong individual rational action and historical efficiency are not held by all
entrepreneurship researchers. Many subscribe to a model of bounded rationality where action is intendedly
rational but blurred by uncertainty, ambiguity and lack of information. We discuss these models below as
we develop our argument.
12
We found this somewhat surprising because as Hannan and Carroll (1992: 199) note, “Images of rationality in
organization building seem to focus on…the causes of attempts to start organizations.” Many ecologists
would not necessarily view themselves as rational action theorists.
13
We doubt that this task will be taken on with eagerness by ecologists themselves. Indeed, Hannan and Carroll
(1992; 194-8) argue against the fashionable practice of motivating macro theories by building up from
micro assumptions and models, contending that this increases the fragility of a macro theory. They propose
instead that macro theories be designed for robustness with respect to micro assumptions, and point to
Darwin’s theory of natural selection as an example.
14
The consequences of different models of entrepreneurship on organizational populations are also of great
potential interest. See, for instance, Ruef's (2004) analysis of how entrepreneurial inertia might generate
population cycles of boom and bust.
15
De alio firms also obtained higher market shares in the American television receiver industry (Klepper and
Simons 2000).
16
Specifically, Khessina (2003) found that de novo firms introduced products with performance parameters that
improved over those of these firms’ previous best products at a significantly higher rate than de alio firms.
Additionally, de novo firms introduced products with performance parameters that were among the top of
the industry (i.e., with performance parameters close to the technological frontier) at a significantly higher
rate than de alio firms. Hence, de novo firms outperformed de alio firms in product innovation.
17
We say intendedly rational because location in the non-overlapped region of a particular dimensionalization
of the niche may or may not lead to a greater chance of success once the enterprise is operating. That
question would need to be demonstrated in a separate empirical study of organizational viability or
mortality.
18
The empirical analysis uses a novel conceptualization strategy the investigators call “structural event
analysis” pioneered by Ruef (2002). In a nutshell, this technique uses combinatorial methods to generate all
possible combinations of potential group members (based on the social characteristics of theoretical
interest) and to specify the expectations of their distributions under different assumptions about sorting
implied by the hypotheses; it then uses Poisson regressions to account for deviations between the sample
data and these expected distributions.
7. REFERENCES
Aldrich, H.E. and Wiedenmayer, G. (1993). From traits to rates: An ecological perspective on organizational
foundings. In J. Katz and R., Advances in Entrepreneurship, Firm Emergence, and Growth, (pp.145-195).
Greenwich, CT: JAI Press.
Banbury, C.M., & Mitchell, W. (1995). The effect of introducing important incremental innovations on market
share and business survival. Strategic Management Journal, 16, S161-S182.
Barnett, W.P., & Freeman, J. (2001). Too much of a good thing? Product proliferation and organizational
failure. Organization Science, 12, 539-558.
Barnett W.P., & Sorenson, O. (2002). The Red Queen in organizational creation and development. Industrial
and Corporate Change, 11, 289-325.
Barnett, W.P., Swanson, A.N., & Sorenson, O. (2003). Asymmetric selection among organizations. Industrial
and Corporate Change, 12, 673-695.
Baron, J.N. (2004). Employing identities in organizational ecology. Industrial and Corporate Change,13,3-32.
Barron, D.N. (1992). The analysis of count data: Overdispersion and autocorrelation. In P.V. Marsden,
Sociological Methodology 1992 (pp. 179-220). Oxford. Basil Blackwell.
Barron, D.N., West, E., & Hannan, M.T. (1994). A time to grow and a time to die: Growth and mortality of
credit unions in New York City, 1914-1990. American Journal of Sociology, 100, 381-421.
Baum J.A.C., & Haveman, H.A. (1996). Love thy neighbor? Differentiation and agglomeration in the
Manhattan hotel industry, 1898-1990. Administrative Science Quarterly, 42, 304-338.
Baum, J.A.C., Korn, H.J., & Kotha, S. (1995). Dominant designs and population dynamics in
telecommunications services: Founding and failure of facsimile transmission service organizations, 19651992. Social Science Research, 24, 97-135.
Baum, J.A.C., & Oliver, C. (1996). Towards an institutional ecology of organizational founding. Academy of
Management Journal, 39, 1378-1427.
Baum, J.A.C., & Singh, J.V. (1994). “Organizational niches and the dynamics of organizational mortality.”
American Journal of Sociology, 100, 346-380.
Boone, C., Brocheler, V., & Carroll, G.R. (2000). Custom service: Application and tests of resource-partitioning
theory among Dutch auditing firms for 1896 to 1992. Organization Studies, 21, 355-381.
Boone, C., Carroll, G.R., & van Witteloostuijn, A. (2002). “Resource distributions and market partitioning:
Dutch daily newspapers, 1968 to 1994. American Sociological Review, 67, 408-31.
Brittain, J.W., & Freeman, J. (1986). Entrepreneurship in the semiconductor industry. Unpublished manuscript,
University of California, Berkeley, CA.
Bruderl, J., & Schussler, R. (1990). Organizational mortality: The liabilities of newness and adolescence.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, 530-547.
Bruderl, J., Preisendorfer, P., & Ziegler, R. (1992). Survival chances of newly founded business organizations.
American Sociological Review, 57, 227-242.
Carroll, G.R. (1985). Concentration and specialization: Dynamics of niche width in populations of
organizations. American Journal of Sociology, 90, 1262-1283.
Carroll, G.R. (1997). Long-term evolutionary change in organizational populations. Industrial and Corporate
Change, 6,119-43.
Carroll, G.R., Bigelow, L.S., Seidel, M.D., & Tsai, L.B. (1996). The fates of de novo and de alio producers in
the American automobile industry 1885-1981. Strategic Management Journal, 17,117-137.
Carroll, G.R., & Delacroix, J. (1982). Organizational mortality in the newspaper industries of Argentina and
Ireland: An ecological approach. Administrative Science Quarterly, 27,169-198.
Carroll, G.R., Delacroix, J., & Goodstein, J. (1988). The political environments of organizations: An ecological
view. Research in Organizational Behavior, 10, 359-392.
Carroll, G.R., & Hannan, M.T. (2000). The demography of corporations and industries. Princeton, NJ:
Princeton University Press.
Carroll, G.R., & Huo, Y.P. (1986). Organizational task and institutional environments in ecological perspective:
Findings from the local newspaper industry. American Journal of Sociology, 91, 838-873.
Carroll, G.R., & Khessina, O.M. (2004). Organizational and corporate demography. In D.L. Poston, Jr & M.
Micklin (Eds.), Handbook of Population (forthcoming). Plenum/Kluwer.
Carroll, G.R., & Swaminathan, A. (2000). Why the microbrewery movement? Organizational dynamics of
resource partitioning in the U.S. brewing industry. American Journal of Sociology, 106, 715-762.
Carroll, G.R., Dobrev, S., & Swaminathan, A. (2002). Organizational processes of resource partitioning.
Research in Organizational Behavior, 24, 1-40.
Delacroix, J., & Carroll, G.R. (1983). Organizational foundings: An ecological study of the newspaper
industries of Argentina and Ireland. Administrative Science Quarterly, 28, 274-291.
Delacroix, J., Swaminathan, A., & Solt, M.E. (1989). Density dependence versus population dynamics: An
ecological study of the failing in the California wine industry. American Sociological Review, 54, 245-262.
Dobbin, F., & Dowd, T. (1997). How policy shapes competition: Early railroad foundings in Massachusetts.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 42, 501-529.
Dobrev, S.D. (2001). Revisiting organizational legitimation: Cognitive diffusion and sociopolitical factors in the
evolution of Bulgarian newspaper enterprises, 1846-1992. Organization Studies, 22, 419-444.
Dobrev, S.D., Kim, T.Y., & Hannan, M.T. (2001). Dynamics of niche width and resource partitioning.
American Journal of Sociology, 106, 1299-1337.
Delacroix, J., & Swaminathan, A. (1991). Cosmetic, speculative, and adaptive organizational change in the
wine industry: A longitudinal study. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36, 631-661.
Fichman, M., & Levinthal, D.A. (1991). Honeymoons and the liability of adolescence: A new perspective on
duration dependence in social and organizational relationships. Academy of Management Review, 16, 44268.
Freeman, J. (1990). Ecological analysis of semiconductor firm mortality. In J.V. Singh (Ed.), Organizational
Evolution: New Directions (pp. 53-77). Newbury Park, CA: Sage.
Freeman, J., Carroll, G.R., & Hannan, M.T. (1983). The liability of newness: Age dependence in organizational
death rates. American Sociological Review, 48, 692-710.
Halliday, T.C., Powell, M.J., & Granfors, M.W. (1987). Minimalist organizations: Vital events in state bar
associations, 1870-1930. American Sociological Review, 52, 456-471.
Hannan, M.T. (1986). Competitive and institutional processes in organizational ecology. Technical Report 8613, Department of Sociology, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY.
Hannan, M.T. (1986). Organizational population dynamics and social change. European Sociological Review 4,
95-109.
Hannan, Michael T. (1992). Rationality and Robustness in Multilevel Systems. In J.S. Coleman (Ed.),
Rational Action in Sociology, (pp. 120-135). Newbury Park: Sage.
Hannan, M.T. (1997). Inertia, density and the structure of organizational populations: Entries in European
automobile industries, 1886-1981. Organization Studies, 18, 193-228.
Hannan, M.T. (1998). Rethinking age dependence in organizational mortality: Logical formalizations. American
Journal of Sociology, 104, 85-123.
Hannan, M.T., & Carroll, G.R. (1992). Dynamics of organizational populations: Density, legitimation, and
competition. New York: Oxford University Press.
Hannan, M.T., Carroll, G.R., Dobrev, S.D., & Han, J. (1998). Organizational mortality in European and
American automobile industries part I: Revisiting the effects of age and size.European Sociological
Review, 14, 279-302.
Hannan, M.T., Carroll, G.R., Dundon, E.A., & Torres, J.C. (1995). Organizational evolution in a multinational
context: Entries of automobile manufacturers in Belgium, Britain, France, Germany, and Italy. American
Sociological Review, 60, 509-528.
Hannan, M.T., & Freeman, J. (1987). The ecology of organizational founding: American labor unions, 18361985. American Journal of Sociology, 92, 910-943.
Hannan, M.T., & Freeman, J. (1988). The ecology of organizational mortality: American labor unions, 18361985. American Journal of Sociology, 94, 25-52.
Hannan, M.T., & Freeman, J. (1989). Organizational ecology. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
Hargens, L.L. (2000). Using the literature: Reference networks, reference contexts and the social structure of
scholarship. American Sociological Review, 65, 846-65.
Haveman, H.A., & Cohen, L.E. (1994). The ecological dynamics of careers: The impact of organizational
founding, dissolution, and merger on job mobility. American Journal of Sociology, 100, 104-152.
Ingram, P., & Inman, C. (1996). Institutions, intergroup competition, and the evolution of hotel populations
around Niagara Falls. Administrative Science Quarterly, 41, 629 -658.
Ingram, P., & Simons, T. (2000). State formation, ideological competition, and the ecology of Israeli workers
cooperatives, 1920-1992. Administrative Science Quarterly, 45, 25-53.
Jaffee, J. (2000). The resource partitioning of a corporate legal market: The proliferation of specialist law firms
in Silicon Valley, 1966-1997. Paper presented at American Sociological Association Meetings,
Washington, DC.
Jovanovic, B. (2004). The pre-producers. Paper presented at the Conference on Strategy and Ecology,
Washington University, Olin School of Business, St. Louis, MO.
Khessina, O.M. (2003). Entry mode, technological innovation and firm survival in the worldwide optical disk
drive industry, 1983-1999. Unpublished Ph.D. Thesis, University of California, Berkeley, CA.
Khessina, O.M., & Carroll, G.R. (2002). Product dynamics of de novo and de alio firms in the worldwide
optical disk drive industry, 1983-1999. Paper presented at the Academy of Management Meetings, Denver,
CO.
Klepper, S. (2001). Employee startups in high-tech industries. Industrial and Corporate Change, 10, 639-674.
Klepper, S., & Simons, K.L. (2000). Dominance by birthright: Entry of prior radio producers and competitive
ramifications in the U.S. television receiver industry. Strategic Management Journal, 21, 997-1016.
Land, K.C., Davis, W.R., & Blau, J.R. (1994). Organizing the boys of summer: The evolution of U.S. minorleague baseball, 1883-1990. American Journal of Sociology, 100, 781-813.
Lomi, A. (1995a). The population and community ecology of organizational founding: Italian cooperative bans,
1936-1989. European Sociological Review, 11, 75-98.
Lomi, A. (1995b). The population and community ecology of organizational founding: Location dependence
and unobserved heterogeneity. Administrative Science Quarterly 40: 111-145.
March, J.G. (1978). Bounded Rationality, Ambiguity, and the Engineering of Choice. Bell Journal of
Economics, 9, 587-608.
March, J.G. and J.P. Olsen. (1989). Rediscovering institutions: The organizational basis of politics. New York:
Free Press.
Marrett, C.B. (1980). Influences on the rise of new organizations: The formation of women's medical
societies. Administrative Science Quarterly, 25, 185-199.
McKendrick, D.G., & Carroll, G.R. (2001). On the genesis of organizational forms: Evidence from the market
for disk drive arrays. Organization Science, 12, 661-82.
McKendrick, D.G., Jaffee, J., Carroll, G.R., & Khessina, O.M. (2003). In the bud? Disk array producers as a
(possibly) emergent organizational form. Administrative Science Quarterly, 48, 60-93
Minkoff, D.C. (1997). The sequencing of social movements. American Sociological Review, 62, 779-799.
Mitchell, W. (1994). The dynamics of evolving markets: The effects of business sales and age on dissolutions
and divestitures. Administrative Science Quarterly, 39, 575-602.
Olzak, S. (1989). Analysis of events in studies of collective action. Annual Review of Sociology, 15, 119-141.
Olzak, S., & West, E. (1991). Ethnic conflicts and the rise and fall of ethnic newspapers. American Sociological
Review, 56, 458-474.
Olzak, S., & Uhrig, N. (2001). The ecology of tactical overlap among new social movements in West Germany.
American Sociological Review, 66, 694-718.
Park, D.Y., & Podolny, J.M. (2000). The competitive dynamics of status and niche width: U.S. investment
banking, 1920-1950. Industrial and Corporate Change, 9, 377-414.
Pfeffer, J. (1993). Barriers to the advance of organizational science: Paradigm development as a dependent
variable. Academy of Management Review, 18, 599-620.
Philips, D.J. (2002). A genealogical approach to organizational life chances: The parent-progeny transfer among
Silicon Valley law firms. 1946-1996. Administrative Science Quarterly, 47, 474-506.
Podolny, J.M. (1993). A status-based model of market competition. American Journal of Sociology, 98, 829-72.
Pólos, L., Hannan, M.T., & Carroll, G.R. (2002). Foundations of a theory of social forms. Industrial and
Corporate Change, 11, 85-115.
Porter, M.E. (1980). Competitive strategy: Techniques for analyzing industries and competitors. New York:
Free Press.
Rao, H. (1994). The social construction of reputation: Certification contests, legitimation, and the survival of
organizations in the American automobile industry: 1895-1912. Strategic Management Journal, 15, 29-44.
Ruef, M. (2000). The emergence of organizational forms: A community ecology approach. American Journal of
Sociology, 106, 658-714.
Ruef, M. (2002). A structural event approach to the analysis of group composition. Social Networks, 24, 135160.
Ruef, M. (2004). Boom and bust: The effect of entrepreneurial inertia on organizational populations.
Unpublished manuscript, Graduate School of Business, Stanford University, Palo Alto, CA.
Ruef, M., Aldrich, H.E., & Carter, N.M. (2003). The structure of founding teams: Homophily, strong ties, and
isolation among U.S. entrepreneurs. American Sociological Review, 68, 195-222.
Schoonhoven, C.B., Eisenhardt, K.M., & Lyman, K. (1990). Speeding products to market: Waiting time to first
product introduction in new firm. Administrative Science Quarterly, 35, 177-207.
Simons, T., & Ingram, P. (2002). Enemies of the state: Competition over the supply of order and the ecology of
the kibbutz, 1910-1997. Paper presented at the 25th Anniversary of Organizational Ecology Conference,
Stanford University, Palo Alto, CA.
Simons, T., & Ingram, P. (2004). An ecology of identity: Theory and evidence from four populations.Industrial
and Corporate Change,13, 33-60.
Singh, J.V., Tucker, D.J., & House, R.J. (1986). Organizational legitimacy and the liability of newness.
Administrative Science Quarterly, 31, 171-193.
Sørensen, J.B., & Sorenson, O. (2003). From conception to birth: Opportunity perception and resource
mobilization in entrepreneurship. Advances in Strategic Management, 20, 89-117.
Sorenson, O., & Audia, P.G. (2000). The social structure of entrepreneurial activity: Geographic concentration
of footwear production in the U.S., 1940-1989. American Journal of Sociology, 106, 424-62.
Sorenson, O., & Stuart, T.E. (2001). Syndication networks and the spatial distribution of venture capital
investment. American Journal of Sociology, 106, 1546-1588
Stinchcombe, A.L. (1965). Social structure and organizations. In J.G. March (Ed.), Handbook of Organizations.
Chicago: Rand McNally.
Stuart, T.E., & Sorenson, O. (2003). The geography of opportunity: Spatial heterogeneity in founding rates and
the performance of biotechnology firms. Research Policy, 32, 229-253.
Studer-Ellis, E.M. (1995). Springboards to mortarboards: Women's college foundings in Massachusetts, New
York, and Pennsylvania. Social Forces, 73, 1051-1070.
Swaminathan, A. (1995). The proliferation of specialist organizations in the American wine industry, 19411990. Administrative Science Quarterly, 40, 653-680.
Swaminathan, A. (1998). Entry into new market segments in mature industries: Endogenous and exogenous
segmentation in the U.S. brewing industry. Strategic Management Journal, 19, 389-404.
Swaninathan, A., & Delacroix, J. (1991). Differentiation within an organizational population: Additional
evidence from the wine industry. Academy of Management Journal, 34, 679-692.
Swaminathan, A., & Wade, J.B. (2001). Social movement theory and the evolution of new organizational
forms. In C.B. Schoonhoven & E. Romanelli (Eds.), The Entrepreneurship Dynamic: Origins of
Entrepreneurship and the Evolution of Industries (pp. 286-313). Palo Alto, CA: Stanford University Press.
Swanson, A.N. (2002). Form coherence and the fates of de alio and de novo organizations in the U.S. digital
computer industry: 1951-1994. Unpublished Ph.D. dissertation, Stanford University, Palo Alto, CA.
Tucker, D.J., Singh, J.V., & Meinhard, A.G. (1990). Organizational form, population dynamics, and
institutional change: The founding patterns of voluntary organizations. Academy of Management Journal,
33, 151-178.
Tilly, C. (1978). From mobilization to revolution. Reading, MA: Addison-Wesley.
Venkataraman, S. (1997). The distinctive domain of entrepreneurship research. Advances in Entrepreneurship,
Firm Emergence and Growth, 3, 119-138.
Wade, J.B., Swaminathan, A., & Saxon, M.S. (1998). Normative and resource flow consequences of local
regulations in American brewing industry, 1845-1918. Administrative Science Quarterly, 43, 905-935.
West, E. (1995). Organization building in the wake of ethnic conflict: A comparison of three ethnic groups.
Social Forces, 4,1333-1363.