NBER WORKING PAPER SERIES
DECOMPOSING PRODUCTIVITY GROWTH
IN THE U.S. COMPUTER INDUSTRY
Hyunbae Chun
M. Ishaq Nadiri
Working Paper 9267
https://www.nber.org/papers/w9267
NATIONAL BUREAU OF ECONOMIC RESEARCH
1050 Massachusetts Avenue
Cambridge, MA 02138
October 2002
We would like to thank Diego Comin, Boyan Jovanovic, and Edward Wolff for their very helpful suggestions
and Steve Rosenthal for providing the data used in this paper. This research was partially supported by a PSC-
CUNY grant from the City University of New York. The views expressed herein are those of the authors and
not necessarily those of the National Bureau of Economic Research.
© 2002 by Hyunbae Chun and M. Ishaq Nadiri. All rights reserved. Short sections of text, not to exceed two
paragraphs, may be quoted without explicit permission provided that full credit, including © notice, is given
to the source.
Decomposing Productivity Growth in the U.S. Computer Industry
Hyunbae Chun and M. Ishaq Nadiri
NBER Working Paper No. 9267
October 2002
JEL No. D24, O33, O47
ABSTRACT
In this paper, we examine the sources of the productivity growth in the U.S. computer
industry from 1978 to 1999. We estimate a joint production model of output quantity and quality that
distinguishes two types of technological changes: process and product innovations. Based on the
estimation results, we decompose total factor productivity (TFP) growth rate into the contributions
of process and product innovations and scale economies. The results show that product innovation
associated with better quality accounts for about 30 percent of the TFP growth in the computer
industry. Furthermore, we find that the TFP acceleration in the computer industry in the late 1990s
is mainly derived from a rapid increase in product innovation.
Hyunbae Chun M. Ishaq Nadiri
Department of Economics Department of Economics
Queens College New York University
City University of New York 269 Mercer Street
65-30 Kissena Blvd. 7th Floor
Flushing, NY 11367 New York, NY 10003
[email protected] and NBER
[email protected]
1. Introduction
During the last few decades, there has been a remarkable productivity growth in
the production of information technology (IT) products such as computers,
communications equipment, and semiconductors. A typical measure of productivity is
total factor productivity (TFP), defined as the amount of output produced from a given
amount of input. Hence, traditional TFP approach mainly focuses on how much
productivity growth is commensurate to the improvement in the technological efficiency
of production process (process innovation).
In contrast to process innovation, productivity growth can take place in the
improvement of output quality (product innovation). In particular, improvement in output
quality is one of the most prevailing characteristics in the IT production such as
microprocessor speed, the capacity of storage devices and memory, etc. This suggests
that technical innovation associated with better quality can be an important source of the
TFP growth in the IT-producing industry. Therefore, the identification of both process
and product innovations is crucial to explore the sources of productivity growth in the IT-
producing industry.
As Hulten (2001) pointed out, however, the TFP approach is silent about product
innovation. Although some recent studies by Jorgenson and Stiroh (2000) and Oliner and
Sichel (2000) have attempted to measure the TFP growth in the IT-producing industry,
there have been few studies that distinguish the contribution of two different technical
innovations in the productivity growth in this industry.
In this paper, we examine the sources of the productivity growth in the U.S.
computer industry from 1978 to 1999. The novelty of this paper is that we separate two
1
different technical changes in TFP growth: product innovation associated with better
quality and process innovation associated with more quantity. We also distinguish
technical change from other factors affecting TFP growth, such as economies of scale.1
Using both the hedonic (quality-adjusted) and list (quality-unadjusted) prices, we
construct the variables of output quantity and quality. Then, we formulate the joint
production model of output quantity and quality, and estimate the joint optimization
conditions of quantity and quality together with a general cost structure that accounts for
scale economies and markups. Based on the estimation results, we decompose the TFP
growth in the computer industry into three effects of process and product innovations and
economies of scale.
The findings in this paper are summarized as follows. First, we find that technical
change associated with process innovation is a major factor contributing to the TFP
growth in the computer industry, which accounts for almost half of the TFP growth.
However, product-oriented technical change also explains about 30 percent of the TFP
growth in the computer industry while the effect of scale economies explains about 20
percent of the TFP growth. Hence, technical changes in total contribute almost 80 percent
of the TFP growth in the computer industry. The results suggest that the high growth rate
of TFP in the computer industry depends not on non-technological factors (i.e., scale
economies associated with rapid growth in the demand for computers), but rather on
faster technological innovations.
Second, we find a substantial size of markups in pricing of both output quantity
and quality. In particular, the findings show that markup for quality is larger than markup
1
The conventional index of TFP based on the Divisa index can be biased to measure the contribution of
technical change to productivity growth if the assumptions underlying its derivation are not satisfied. The
2
for quantity, and suggest that the computer market is more competitive in quantity than in
quality.
Third, we find that the TFP contribution from product innovation rapidly rose in
the late 1990s, while the contribution from process innovation and economies of scale
changed little. The increasing trend in product innovation challenges the prediction of the
industry life-cycle theory, which states that new industries experience product innovation
early and process innovation later. The TFP acceleration in the computer industry from
the early to late 1990s was mainly derived from rapid growth in product innovation,
while the TFP contribution from process innovation and scale economies remained
almost unchanged. In particular, the acceleration in product innovation in the computer
industry explains approximately 20 percent of the acceleration in the productivity growth
of the aggregate economy from the early to late 1990s.
The paper is organized as follows. In section 2, we measure output quantity and
quality, formulate the model for empirical implementation, and present the method for
TFP decomposition. Section 3 describes the data used in this study. Section 4 presents
results for estimation and TFP decomposition. Section 5 discusses the contribution from
the computer industry to the productivity growth in the aggregate economy. The
conclusion is included in section 6.
biases can be due to the presence of economies of scale, markup, etc (Nadiri and Prucha, 2001).
3
2. Empirical Model
Measuring Output Quantity and Quality
Product innovation takes place in the improvement of quality or in the
introduction of new products that have better quality. Technical change associated with
product innovation does not necessarily result in increases in physical units of output.
Hence, measuring changes in output quality, given physical units of output, is crucial to
distinguish product innovation from process innovation.2
The hedonic price method provides us a viable solution to measure the
improvement of output quality. The hedonic price corrects the list price of output for
changes in product attributes that characterize changes in output quality as:
P
PY = (1)
YS
where PY is the hedonic (quality-adjusted) price of output, P is the list (quality-
unadjusted) price of output, and YS is the index of output quality. Equation (1) shows that
the hedonic price falls as output quality rises, given the list price. Moreover, we note that
the hedonic price also declines as the list price falls, for example, in connection with the
decline in markup. The hedonic price includes not only product quality but also other
factors affecting the list price such as the market demand.3
2
Instead of measuring the quality of output, Thompson and Waldo (2000) estimate the contribution from
product innovation to the productivity slowdown using the consumption data.
3
The importance of the demand condition in the hedonic price method is also emphasized in the studies by
Rosen (1974) and Ohta (1975). For example, this method described in equation (3) was used in the study
by Raff and Trajtenberg (1997) that constructed the U.S. automobile quality in the early twentieth century.
4
After correcting for the demand factors from the hedonic price, the quality of
output is given by
P
YS = . (2)
PY
The quantity of output (physical units of output) can be obtained from dividing the
nominal value of production by the list price of output,
V
YQ = Y (3)
P
where YQ is the quantity of output and VY is the nominal value of production. Thus, the
quality-adjusted output can be obtained from either dividing the nominal value of
production by the hedonic price or multiplying output quantity by output quality,
V V P
Y = Y = Y = YQ YS . (4)
PY P PY
Empirical Specification
A firm produces two outputs of quantity and quality by employing inputs. The
firm chooses both output quantity and quality to maximize its profits,
5
π (YQ , YS ) = YQ P(YQ , YS ) − C (YQ , YS ) (5)
where YQ is the quantity of output, YS is the quality of output, P(YQ,YS) is the inverse
demand function, and C(YQ,YS) is the cost function. The joint optimization of output
quantity and quality is based on a simple model formulated by Dorfman and Steiner
(1954).4 The quality improvement shifts the quantity demand curve to the right and raises
the curve of cost.
The profit maximization problem yields two first-order conditions,
P (YQ , YS ) + YQ PQ (YQ , Y ) = CQ (YQ , YS ) (6)
YQ PS (YQ , Y ) = CS (YQ , YS ) (7)
where PS (PQ) is the willingness to pay for an additional unit of output quality (quantity)
given quantity (quality), and CS (CQ) is the marginal cost of producing an additional unit
of output quality (quantity).
P − CQ
The first condition is well known as the price-cost margin ( ) that depends
P
on the demand elasticity of output quantity. The second condition determines the optimal
production of output quality. The left-hand side of equation (7) measures increases in
revenue by way of raising the price. Since PS represents the willingness to pay for one
more unit of quality, the supply of the better quality can increase the revenue by way of
6
raising the price. Thus, we can expect the positive sign for PS in contrast to the negative
sign for PQ. The right-hand side of equation (7) measures the marginal cost associated
with an increase in the production of quality. Therefore, the optimal choice of output
quality depends not only on the demand condition for quality but also on the cost
structure of the quality production.5
To examine a general cost structure of quality production that allows increasing or
decreasing returns to scale, we employ a translog cost function to describe the technology
of the firm as:
ln(ctv ) = β 0 + β L ln wt + β K ln K t −1 + ∑
j =Q , S
β j ln Y j ,t + βT Tt
1
+ β LL (ln wt ) 2 + β KK (ln K t −1 ) 2 + ∑ β jj (ln Y j ,t ) 2 + βTT Tt 2
2 j =Q , S
+ β LK ln wt ln K t −1 + ∑ β Lj ln wt ln Y j ,t + β LT ln wtTt (8)
j =Q , S
+ ∑
j =Q , S
β Kj ln Kt −1 ln Y j ,t + β KT ln K t −1Tt
+ β QS ln YQ ,t ln YS ,t + ∑
j =Q , S
β jT ln Y j ,tTt
where the variable cost is given by Cv = WLL+WMM and the variable cost and the price of
labor input are normalized by the price of materials, i.e., cv = (Cv/WM) and w=(WL/WM),
respectively. The normalization imposes the homogeneity restriction on the cost function.
4
For example, Dorfman and Steiner (1954) analyzed advertising as a special case of quality. Models with
the joint production of output quantity and quality have been used in many areas such as economic
development (Kremer, 1993) and business cycle (Yorukoglu, 2000).
5
If the cost structure for quality production has a property of constant returns to scale, the choice of quality
production is dependent upon the demand condition, but is independent of the cost structure. Assuming a
7
Kt-1 is a lagged variable of quasi-fixed capital stock and T is an index of process-oriented
technical change that represents shift in the variable cost function.
Applying Shephard’s lemma to the variable cost function, we derive the cost
share equations of variable inputs. The variable cost share equation of labor input is given
by
S L ,t = β L + β LL ln wt + β LK ln K t −1 + ∑β
j =Q , S
Lj ln Y j ,t + β LT Tt (9)
where SL = (WLL/Cv) is the variable cost share of labor input and the variable cost share
of materials can be derived as a residual, SM = (WMM/Cv) = 1-SL.
Using the envelope theorem, we can derive the long-run equilibrium condition for
a quasi-fixed factor of capital. In the long-run equilibrium, the optimal quantity of the
capital stock is determined by the condition that the rental rate of capital is equal to the
magnitude of the reduction in variable cost due to an increase in an additional unit of the
capital stock. This condition yields the variable cost share equation of the capital stock
as:
S K ,t = −( β K + β KK ln K t −1 + β LK ln wt + ∑β
j =Q , S
Kj ln Y j ,t + β KT Tt ) (10)
where SK = (WKK/Cv) is the variable cost share of capital and WK is the rental price of
capital.
simple cost structure with constant returns to scale, several previous studies estimated the demand
condition alone.
8
Rearranging two first-order conditions for profit maximization with respect to
output quantity and quality in equations (6) and (7), we can derive the variable cost share
equations of output quantity and quality as:
∂ ln Ctv
SQ ,t = (1 + µQ )
∂ ln YQ ,t
(11)
1
=(
1 + αQ
)( β Q + β LQ ln wt + β KQ ln K t −1 + ∑
j =Q , S
β Qj ln Y j ,t + β QT Tt )
∂ ln Ctv
S S ,t = (1 + µ S )
∂ ln YS ,t
(12)
1
=(
αS
)( β S + β LS ln wt + β KS ln K t −1 + ∑
j =Q , S
β jS ln Y j ,t + β ST Tt )
where SQ is the variable cost share of output quantity, µQ is the markup for output
quantity, and αQ is the inverse demand elasticity with respect to output quantity. SS, µS,
and αS are similarly defined for the quality of output. The markup rises as the inverse
demand elasticity increases. The profit maximization conditions imply that the optimal
supply of quantity and quality are jointly determined by not only the markups (demand
side) but also the cost elasticities (production side).
Decomposition of TFP Growth
The growth rate of TFP is traditionally defined as the difference between the
growth rate of output and the growth rate of all inputs. Since the growth rate of the
quality-adjusted output (Y) is equal to the sum of growth rates of output quantity and
9
i i
quality ( Yt = ∑ Y j ,t ) as shown in (4), the rate of TFP growth in a two-output case can be
j =Q , S
given by
i i 1 i
TFPt = ∑Y
j =Q , S
j ,t − ∑
i= L,M ,K 2
( S i ,t −1 + S i ,t ) X i ,t (13)
where a dot over the variable denotes the rate of growth, S i is the total cost share of input
i
i, and X i is the growth rate of input i.
Following the methodology of the TFP decomposition in a multiple-output case
proposed by Denny, Fuss, and Waverman (1981) and Nadiri and Nandi (1999), we can
decompose the growth rate of TFP into three factors as:
i 1 i 1 i
TFP = (1 − ) Y Q + (1 − ) Y S − ηT (14)
ρQ ρS
1 − η Kv
ρj = ,
η vj
∂ ln C v
η Kv = ,
∂ ln K
∂ ln C v
η vj = ,
∂ ln Y j
ηTv
ηT = , and
1 − η Kv
∂ ln C v
ηTv = for j = Q, S
∂T
10
where ηKv is the variable cost elasticity with respect to the capital stock, ηQv and ηSv are the
variable cost elasticities with respect to output quantity and quality, respectively, and ηTv
is the variable cost elasticity with respect to the time variable. Scale economies are
measured as the inverse of cost elasticity with respect to output quantity. After correcting
for the effect of a quasi-fixed factor of the capital stock on the variable cost, ρ Q measures
scale economies in the long-run. There are economies of scale if ρ Q is greater than one.
In a similar vein, ρ S measures the degree of the cost efficiency for product innovation
which can be a source of productivity growth if ρ S is greater than one. Process-oriented
technical change can be measured with −ηT that represents a shift in the cost function.
On the right-hand side of equation (14), the first term is scale effect, the second
term is the effect of product innovation (quality effect), and the last term is the effect of
process innovation.6
3. Data
Data used in this study are obtained from the NBER-CES Manufacturing Industry
Database.7 Using the Annual Survey of Manufactures (ASM) and the Census of
Manufactures (CM), the NBER-CES database constructed the four-digit industry data on
gross output, employment, payroll, materials, capital stock, and various industry-specific
price indexes. Among the detailed industries, we use four computer industries as
6
Nadiri and Nandi (1998) decomposed scale effect into several exogenous components such as changes in
exogenous demands, factor prices, etc. Unless either quantity or quality is assumed to be exogenous, we
cannot decompose the scale and quality effects into other exogenous factors because of the property of the
joint determination of quantity and quality.
7
See Bartelsman and Gray (1996) for the detailed description of the NBER-CES database.
11
Electronic computers (3571), Computer storage devices (3572), Computer terminals
(3575), and Computer peripheral equipment (3577) (SIC 1987 codes in parentheses)8.
However, the NBER-CES database covers only up to 1996, so we expanded the
database to 1999 with the latest publications of the ASM and CM. The industry
classification for the post-1996 data of the CM and ASM is based on the North American
Industry Classification System (NAICS). Using the bridge tables published by the Census
Bureau, all variables for the four industries are converted into those based on the SIC
1987.
Gross output in current prices is defined as the sum of shipments and changes in
inventories of finished goods. Using the ratio of the list price to the hedonic price as
shown in equation (2), we constructed the variable of output quality. We obtained the
hedonic price for computer products from the Bureau of Economic Analysis (BEA).9
The list price is obtained from the Current Industrial Reports (CIR) published by
the Census Bureau. The CIR includes the value of shipments as well as the quantity of
shipments in number of physical units. The list price was constructed by dividing the
nominal value of shipments by the physical units of shipments. Note that the BEA
hedonic prices are based on products rather than industries (BEA, 1998). For example,
the BEA estimated the hedonic price of printers, but did not provide the hedonic prices of
other computer peripheral equipment such as plotters and input-output devices that are
included in the computer peripheral equipment industry (SIC 3577). For consistency
8
We exclude Communication equipment (366) and Semiconductors and related devices (3674) because
hedonic prices are not available for most products in Communication equipment and for Semiconductor-
related devices.
9
See BEA (1998) for the details on sources and methods of the hedonic price indexes. The earlier hedonic
price indexes constructed by the BEA are also found in Cole, Chen, Barquin-Stolleman, Dulberger,
Helvacian, and Hodge (1986).
12
between the list and hedonic prices, we also constructed the list prices at the product
level. In contrast to the CM and ASM data, the CIR is not available before 1977.
Therefore, we restricted the sample period from 1977 to 1999.
Furthermore, we made some adjustments in variables in the NBER-CES database.
Since the payrolls in the NBER-CES database do not include supplemental labor costs of
social security contributions and fringe benefits, we include these supplemental costs into
the payrolls of workers. Since non-production worker hours are not available in the ASM
and CM data sets, production worker hours are used to construct the hourly wage rate of
all employees. The cost of materials measured in the CM and ASM data are adjusted in
two ways. The cost of purchased services is not included in the cost of materials in the
CM and ASM. The cost of purchased services obtained from the input-output tables, are
added into the cost of materials. Material inventories are also added into the cost of
materials: the work-in-process inventories are distributed into labor and materials using
the variable cost shares of inputs (Norsworthy and Jang, 1993).
We used the capital stock from the NBER-CES database that converted the 3-digit
level capital stock constructed by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System
(FRB) into the 4-digit level by assuming that the asset types are the same for all 4-digit
industries within a common 3-digit industry.10 The before-tax user cost of capital is
defined as:
qK (1 − ζ K − uz K )(δ K + r )
WK =
1− u
13
where qK is the investment price deflator, ζK is the rate of investment tax credit, u is the
corporate income tax rate, δK is the depreciation rate of capital, zK is the present value of
capital consumption allowances, and r is the real rate of return.
[Table 1]
Table 1 presents the average annual growth rate of each variable for the period
1978-1999. The hedonic price fell at an annual rate of 16.87 percent on average for the
four computer industries. In particular, the hedonic price in the electronic computers
industry decreased more rapidly than those in the other three industries. However, the
growth rate of the hedonic price is not necessarily the same as the growth rate of quality
because the hedonic price also falls as the list price decreases. The growth rate of quality
is defined as the growth rate of the list price minus the growth rate of the hedonic price.
A lower hedonic price as well as a higher list price can result in a better quality. In
addition to declines in the hedonic prices, the list prices have also fallen for all
industries.11
After correcting for changes in the list prices, the annual growth rate of the quality
improvement is about 12 percent on average for all industries from 1978 to 1999. This
suggests that the improvement in true quality is smaller than changes in the hedonic
price. Quality improvements are significantly different across industries. In particular, the
10
See Mohr and Gilbert (1996) for the description of the FRB 3-digit capital data.
11
For example, Berndt, Dulberger, and Rappaport (2001) reported the list prices of desktop and mobile
computers during the last quarter-century, and found that the list price of desktop computers rose annually
by 6.8 percent between 1976 and 1989, and then fell again annually by 13.0 percent between 1989 and
1999.
14
quality improvement in electronic computers has been faster than those in the other three
computer products.
In a similar way, the growth rate of output quantity is defined as the growth rate
of the nominal output minus the growth rate of the list price. The average annual growth
rate of quantity is about 15 percent for all industries. Except for the computer terminals
industry, the annual growth rates of output quantity for the other three industries are
between 13.28 and 15.71 percent. This implies that the computer industries have a
smaller variation in the growth rate of quantity than in that of quality.
The growth rate of the quality-adjusted output, that is the sum of the growth rates
of quantity and quality, is about 27 percent. This implies that quality improvement
contributes almost a half of the growth of the quality-adjusted output.
In contrast to a rapid growth of both output quantity and quality, the growth rates
of labor and capital inputs are relatively low. In particular, the growth rate of labor input
has been almost constant. Warnke (1996) found that the computer industry enjoyed a
faster growth in employment between 1960 and 1984, but began to shed jobs rapidly
from 1984 to 1995. She argues that employment declines, especially associated with
cutting low skilled and production workers, are attributable to changes in market
structure, a faster factory automation, and international competition.12
4. Empirical Results
We estimate a system of equations consisting of the variable cost function, the
variable cost share equations of labor and capital, and two optimality conditions for
15
output quantity and quality using the non-linear three-stage least squares (3SLS). We use
a set of instrumental variables: lagged variables and a few macroeconomic variables such
as oil price, military expenditures, and the number of population.
[Table 2]
The optimal choice of output quantity and quality depends on two different
demand conditions as well as cost structures that are jointly estimated in this study. The
parameter estimates of the model are shown in Table 2 and the majority of the parameter
estimates are statistically significant. We introduced the industry dummy variables for
intercepts in all equations, and also allow the industry dummy variables for time
coefficient to capture different process innovations among the four industries.
Demand Elasticity and Markup
In Table 2, the coefficient estimate of αQ is about –0.33, which implies that the
quantity demand elasticity with respect to the list price, holding output quality constant,
is about -3.05. The estimate of the inverse demand elasticity with respect to quantity is
similar to the findings of Stavins (1997) which estimated the demand elasticities for
personal computers (PCs) using micro-level data between 1976 and 1988.13 After
controlling for characteristics of differentiated products, she found relatively elastic price
12
The productivity growth in the computer industry could be affected by this change in the production
structure.
13
Without correcting for changes in product quality, an earlier study of Chow (1967) found that the
demand elasticity for mainframe computers is close to -1. Using the data from the banking and insurance
firms in the late 1980s, however, a recent study by Hendel (1999) found more elastic demand for PCs than
16
demand elasticities ranging between -2.9 and -7.2. Our estimate of the quantity demand
elasticity is close to the lower bound of Stavins’ estimates. Since we expect that the
demand for mainframe computers is less elastic than the demand for PCs, the average
demand elasticity, including all types of electronic computers, may be lower than that of
PCs. However, there are few comparable studies on the demand elasticities for the other
computer industries such as storage devices, terminals, and printers. This estimate of the
demand elasticity implies that the markup for output quantity is about 0.49.
The coefficient estimate of αS in Table 2 implies that the demand elasticity with
respect to output quality is 1.91. The finding suggests that the quality demand is less
elastic than the quantity demand, and subsequently the markup associated with quality is
greater than that associated with quantity. Hence, this suggests that the computer product
market is more competitive in quantity than in quality.
Using the data for 19 OECD countries, Oliveira-Martins, Scarpetta, and Pilat
(1996) estimated markups for 36 manufacturing industries at the 3-digit level. In their
results, higher markups were estimated for tobacco products, drugs and medicines, and
office and computing machinery, while lower markups were estimated for footwear,
wearing apparel, and motor vehicles. Their markup estimate for office and computing
machinery industry from 1970 to 1992 is about 0.6, which is very high. Their estimate
lies between our markup estimates of the output quantity and quality. This implies that
without distinguishing the demand for output quantity and quality, the average markup
can overestimate the markup associated with quantity and can underestimate that
associated with quality. Furthermore, a high markup in the computer industry is in part
those of Stavins (1997). See Davis (2000) for an overview of modeling the demand for differentiated
products.
17
due to a high markup associated with quality. In other words, a high markup in this
industry can be attributed to technological characteristics rather than to the market
power.14
Cost Elasticity and Scale
Table 3 presents the short-run and long-run cost elasticities with respect to output
quantity and quality, input prices, a quasi-fixed factor of the capital stock, and time
variable. The short-run implies that production is conducted when the level of the capital
stock is fixed.
[Table 3]
The short-run variable cost elasticity of output quantity is 0.86 implying that a 1
percent increase in the production of output quantity incurs an increase of about 0.86
percent in the variable cost. One of the interesting results is that the cost elasticity of
output quality is smaller than that of output quantity. This suggests that the production of
14
A time-series pattern of markup is an interesting issue because it gives a hint for changes in the market
structure of the computer industry. For example, Stavins (1997) showed that the demand elasticity for PCs
rose between 1977 and 1988 because of the entrance of several IBM-compatible PCs. This implies that the
PC industry became more competitive in this period. However, the number of firms in the PC industry
increased between 1978 and 1990, but decreased between 1990 and 1999, which suggests that there could
be a possible structural break in the nature of competition in the pre- and post-1990 periods. However, it is
difficult to conclude that the computer market became less competitive in the 1990s based on the observed
trend in the number of firms. Filson (2001) showed that the number of firms in the electronic computer
marker increased from the 1970s to the 1980s, but decreased from the 1990s while those in the printer
market increased from the 1970s to the 1990s. Stavins (1995) also examined the entry and exit of firms in
the PC market. To explain changes in the market structure of the computer industry, Bresnahan and
Greenstein (1999) suggest technological competition between computer platforms, not firms, and find that
competition in the computer market changed little over time with the aspect of platform competition. Since
we formulate the model with time-invariant markups for quantity and quality, this issue is beyond the scope
of this paper.
18
quality entails less cost than the production of quantity. Positive signs of cost elasticities
with respect to labor and materials prices imply that higher input prices incur larger costs
of production. The variable cost elasticity of the time variable suggests that the variable
cost has declined about 7.7 percent annually, given production of the same amount of
output quantity and quality.
In the long-run, cost can be minimized with the adjustment of capital. Hence, we
may expect that the cost elasticities are smaller in the long-run than in the short-run. For
example, the cost elasticity of output quantity of 0.79 in the long-run is smaller than 0.86
in the short-run.
Scale economies arise when production expansion causes a less than proportional
increase in inputs and therefore in costs. Thus, scale economies are considered as a
source of productivity growth. However, scale economies are different from technical
change because lower unit costs of production are associated with the expansion of
production via larger sizes of plants. In contrast to a case of the homogenous product,
production expansion in the computer industry does not properly represent increases in
output quantity because production can increase with more quantity as well as with more
quality. If we measure the quantity of output with a conventional method, i.e., deflating
the nominal value of output by the hedonic price, the production expansion based with
this output can take place in both producing a better product and producing more units of
the same product.15
Note that scale economies can be measured as the inverse of cost elasticity with
respect to output quantity after controlling for technical changes. Unless we distinguish
19
the production expansion through improvements in product quality from increases in
physical units of output, a conventional scale estimate measures the average of the
marginal cost associated with better quality as well as the marginal cost associated with
more quantity. Therefore, in this paper, we assume that scale economies can arise only
through the expansion of physical units of product, given quality. The output expansion
effect through quality improvement on changes in costs can be regarded as a different
source of productivity growth.
Scale estimates in both the long-run and short-run for all four industries are
greater than one, which suggests the presence of increasing returns to scale. The scale in
the long-run is on average 1.16. In particular, the scale is slightly smaller in the electronic
computers industry than in the other three industries.
Decomposition of TFP Growth
Using the methodology described in equation (14), Table 4 presents the
decomposed contribution to TFP growth: the effects of process and product innovations
and scale effect. First row in Table 4 shows the TFP growth rates for the four computer
industries. The TFP growth rate in the electronic computers industry (SIC 3571) is
approximately 18 percent and is the highest among the four industries. The TFP growth
rate in the terminals industry is only one-third of the rate in the electronic computers
industry. An average TFP growth rate for the four industries is about 15 percent, but the
TFP growth rates are very heterogeneous among the industries.
15
Klette and Griliches (1996) emphasize inconsistency in scale estimators due to the use of inaccurate
prices of output in a differentiated product market. In their study, the inconsistency can arise when firms
produce differentiated products and their outputs are deflated by a common industry output price.
20
[Table 4]
The contribution of process innovation is on average about 7 percent, which
accounts for almost half of the TFP growth. However, product innovation associated with
better quality appears to be an important contributor as well, explaining about 30 percent
of the TFP growth in the computer industries, while scale effect explains only about 20
percent of the TFP growth. The results imply that the sum of process and product
innovations in total explains more than three-fourths of the TFP growth.16 The results
also suggest that the productivity growth in the computer industries mainly depends upon
the technical changes and, subsequently, is not likely to be vulnerable to changes in the
demand for computer products.
Except for the storage devices industry (SIC 3572), the technical change due to
process innovation explains about half of the TFP growth and the product-oriented
technical change explains about one-third of the TFP growth. In the storage devices
industry, scale effect accounts for almost half of the TFP growth and the product-oriented
technical change accounts for one-third of the TFP growth, while the contribution of the
process innovation is relatively small. The storage devices industry is an industry
producing components of computers while the other three industries mainly produce final
products of computers and peripherals. Thus, we can expect that the production structure
16
In contrast to our estimation results, the study by Nadiri and Prucha (1990) on the U.S. electrical
machinery industry (SIC 36) from 1960 to 1980 found that the scale effect including temporary equilibrium
and adjustment cost effects explains about two-thirds of the TFP growth, and technical change explains the
remaining one-third. Since the electrical machinery industry includes communications equipment and
semiconductors, we also expect a rapid quality improvement in this industry. Hence, their scale estimate
may be overestimated because they didn’t distinguish the output expansion through the quality
improvement from the total output expansion.
21
of the storage devices industry may be close to that of the semiconductor industry
producing microprocessors and memory chips. Since the storage devices industry
develops similar types of products such as hard disks and floppy diskettes and produces
on a large scale with a simpler production process than the other three computer
industries, we may expect that effects of product innovation and economies of scale are
more important than the effect of process innovation.17
5. Implications for Productivity Growth in the Aggregate
Economy
Table 5 shows the TFP growth rate in the U.S. nonfarm business sector for
various periods published by the Bureau of Labor Statistics (BLS). From 1995 through
1999, there was a remarkable resurgence in the productivity growth from the first half of
the 1990s. Determining the source of the productivity resurgence in the aggregate
economy, some recent studies (Jorgenson and Stiroh, 2000; Oliner and Sichel, 2000;
Whelan, 2002) focus on the role of the IT-producing industry such as computers,
communications equipment, and semiconductors.
[Table 5]
17
Although we decomposed the TFP growth in the computer industry into the three factors, it is worthwhile
to pursue the following question. Which factor determines the relative importance of process and product
innovations? Differences in R&D expenditures in product and process innovations in the computer industry
can be a possible answer. Another possible answer can be the difference in the effect of learning-by-doing.
For example, Irwin and Klenow (1994) found a strong effect of learning-by-doing on the cost reduction in
the semiconductor industry.
22
Table 5 also shows that the TFP growth rate in the computer industry accelerated
from the early 1990s to the late 1990s. We also compare our TFP growth rate in the
computer industry with that of Oliner and Sichel (2000) measured by the dual approach.
The TFP growth rate in this study for the period of 1978-1995 is similar to that of their
study. The TFP growth rates are different between this study and their study during the
second half of the 1990s. One of the main reasons for the difference is that Oliner and
Sichel (2000) assume the same cost structure between the IT-producing industry and
other industries.
Using the TFP growth rate in the computer industry, we measure the contribution
from the computer industry to the TFP growth in the aggregate economy, in particular,
the nonfarm business sector. The industry productivity measure, however, is not directly
comparable to the aggregate one because the productivity measure for the aggregate
economy uses value-added while the productivity measure for the industry uses gross
output. To measure the contribution of the computer industry to the aggregate TFP
productivity growth, we use the methodology developed by Domar (1967). The
contribution of the computer industry to the aggregate TFP growth can be obtained from
a weighted sum of the TFP growth rates of the computer industries with the Domar
weights equal to the ratios of industry gross output to aggregate value-added:
i 4 i
TFP t = ∑ wit TFPit (15)
i =1
where wit is the Domar weight for industry i at time period t.
23
The Domar weight of the computer industry is about 1.45 percent in the sample
period. Multiplying the Domar weight with the TFP growth rate in the computer industry,
we can get the contribution from the computer industry to the TFP growth in the
aggregate economy. We find that the contribution is almost one-third of the aggregate
TFP growth. Moreover, the TFP contribution of the computer industry has risen about
two times from the early 1990s to the late 1990s. The rise in the contribution during the
late 1990s is associated with the increase in TFP growth rather than in the Domar weight.
The findings suggest that the TFP acceleration in the computer industry from the early
1990s to the late 1990s explains about 40 percent of the acceleration in the aggregate TFP
growth.
[Figure 1]
Although we find that the TFP growth in the computer industry is an important
source of productivity growth in the aggregate economy, the conventional TFP approach
has limitations in explaining whether a rapid TFP growth in the computer industry is due
to either technological changes or other non-technological factors such as economies of
scale and markups. For example, the studies of Jorgenson and Stiroh (2000), Oliner and
Sichel (2000), and Whelan (2002) employed the dual approach that identifies the TFP
growth in the IT-producing industry using the output price instead of using the output
quantity. Since the dual approach assumes perfect competition in the market structure as
well as constant returns to scale in the production structure, the measures of productivity
24
growth in these studies could be overestimated if the output price is above the marginal
cost, implying a positive markup (Hobijn, 2001) or scale economies prevail.
Table 5 reports the decomposition results of the computer industry’s contribution
to the aggregate TFP growth. First, the scale effect explains almost 20 percent of the
contribution, which suggests that one-fifth of the contribution is associated with non-
technological factors.
Table 5 also shows interesting trends in decompositions of the TFP contribution.
In particular, the contribution from product innovation rose rapidly in the later part of the
sample period while the contribution from process innovation and economies of scale
changed little. Filson (2001) also finds an increasing trend in product innovation in the
computer industry, but a decreasing trend in the automobile industry. The time-series
pattern of product and process innovations in the computer industry challenges the
prediction of the industry life-cycle theory that new industries experience product
innovation early and process innovation later (Gort and Klepper, 1982; Klepper, 1996).
Although the contribution of process innovation to the TFP growth in the
aggregate economy is greater than that of product innovation, an increase in the product-
oriented technical change in the late 1990s explains about 60 percent of the acceleration
in the computer industry’s TFP contribution. The contribution from the non-technological
factor of scale economies also changed little from the early to the late 1990. Therefore,
the findings suggest that the productivity acceleration in the aggregate economy
associated with the computer industry during the late 1990s is largely attributable to
acceleration in the technical change due to product innovation in the computer industry.
25
6. Conclusion
In this paper, we provide an empirical framework for exploring the different
sources of the productivity growth in the U.S. computer industries. We decomposed the
conventionally measured TFP growth into three components: process and product
innovations and economies of scale. The empirical results of this study show that a
technological change associated with both process and product innovations has been a
major source of the TFP growth in the computer industry.
For the sample period of 1978-1999, process innovation explains almost half of
the TFP growth in the computer industry, while product innovation associated with better
quality accounts for about 30 percent of the TFP growth. Furthermore, the contribution
from product innovation to the TFP growth has increased during the sample period, while
the contribution from process innovation has changed little and the contribution from
economies of scale has declined. In particular, the TFP acceleration in the computer
industry in the late 1990s is mainly derived from a rapid increase in product innovation.
The findings on the time-series patterns of product and process innovations in this
paper cast doubt on the prediction of the industry life-cycle theory, which suggests that
new industries experience product innovation early and process innovation later. We have
not explored the determinants of an increasing trend in product innovation in the
computer industry. We intend to address this issue in future work.
26
References
Bartelsman, Eric J. and Wayne Gray, “The NBER Productivity Database,” NBER
Technical Working Paper No. 205, October 1996.
Berndt, Ernst R., Ellen R. Dulberger, and Neal J. Rappaport, “Price and Quality of
Desktop and Mobile Computers: A Quarter Century Historical Overview,” American
Economic Review, 91(2), May 2001, 268-73.
Bresnahan, Timothy F. and Shane Greenstein, “Technological Competition and the
Structure of the Computer Industry,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 47(1), March
1999, 1-40.
Bureau of Economic Analysis, “Computer Prices in the National Accounts: An Update
from the Comprehensive Revision,” National Income and Wealth Division Working
Paper, Bureau of Economic Analysis, August 1998.
Bureau of Labor Statistics, Multifactor Productivity Trends, 1999, Bureau of Labor
Statistics, May 2001.
Chow, Gregory C., “Technological Change and the Demand for Computers,” American
Economic Review, 57(5), December 1967, 1117-30.
Cole, Rosanne, Y. C. Chen, Joan A. Barquin-Stolleman, Ellen R. Dulberger, Nurhan
Helvacian, and James H. Hodge, “Quality-Adjusted Price Indexes for Computer
Processors and Selected Peripheral Equipment,” Survey of Current Business, 66(1),
January 1986, 41-50.
Davis, Peter, “Empirical Models of Demand for Differentiated Products,” European
Economic Review, 44(4-6), May 2000, 993-1005.
Denny, Michael, Melvyn Fuss, and Leonard Waverman “The Measurement and
Interpretation of Total Factor Productivity in Regulated Industries, with an Application to
Canadian Telecommunications,” in Thomas G. Cowing and Rodney E. Stevenson, (eds.),
27
Productivity Measurement in Regulated Industries, New York: Academic Press, 1981,
179-218.
Domar, Evsey, “On the Measurement of Technological Change,” Economic Journal,
71(284), December 1961, 709-29.
Dorfman, Robert and Peter O. Steiner, “Optimal Advertising and Optimal Quality,”
American Economic Review, 44(5), December 1954, 826-36.
Filson, Darren, “The Nature and Effects of Technological Change over the Industry Life
Cycle,” Review of Economic Dynamics, 4(2), 2001, 460-94.
Gort, Michael and Steven Klepper, “Time Paths in the Diffusion of Product Innovations,”
Economic Journal, 92(367), September 1982, 630-53.
Hendel, Igal, “Estimating Multiple-Discrete Choice Models: An Application to
Computerization Returns,” Review of Economic Studies, 66(2), April 1999, 423-46.
Hobijn, Bart, “Is Equipment Price Deflation a Statistical Artifact?” Federal Reserve Bank
of New York Staff Reports No. 139, November 2001.
Hulten, Charles R. “Total Factor Productivity: A Short Bibliography,” in Charles R.
Hulten, Edwin R. Dean, and Michael J. Harper (eds.), New Developments in Productivity
Analysis, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 2001, 1-47.
Irwin, Douglas A. and Peter J. Klenow, “Learning-by-Doing Spillovers in the
Semiconductor Industry,” Journal of Political Economy, 102(6), December 1994, 1200-
27.
Jorgenson, Dale W. and Kevin J. Stiroh, “Rising the Speed Limit: U.S. Economic Growth
in the Information Age,” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, (1), 2000, 125-233.
Klepper, Steven, “Entry, Exit, and Innovation over the Product Life Cycle,” American
Economic Review, 86(3), June 1996, 562-83.
28
Klette, Tor Jakob and Zvi Griliches, “The Inconsistency of Common Scale Estimators
When Output Prices Are Unobserved and Endogenous,” Journal of Applied
Econometrics, 11(4), July-August 1996, 343-61.
Kremer, Michael, “The O-ring Theory of Economic Development,” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 108(3), August 1993, 551-75.
Mohr, Michael F. and Charles E. Gilbert, “Capital Stock Estimates for Manufacturing
Industries: Methods and Data,” Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve System,
March 1996.
Nadiri, M. Ishaq and Banani Nandi, “Technical Change, Markup, Divestiture, and
Productivity Growth in the U.S. Telecommunications Industry,” Review of Economics
and Statistics, 81(3), August 1999, 488-98.
Nadiri, M. Ishaq and Ingmar R. Prucha, “Comparison and Analysis of Productivity
Growth and R&D Investment in the Electrical Machinery Industries of the United States
and Japan,” in Charles. R. Hulten, (ed.), Productivity Growth in Japan and the U.S.,
Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1990, 109-33.
Nadiri, M. Ishaq and Ingmar R. Prucha, “Dynamic Factor Demand Models and
Productivity Analysis,” in Charles. R. Hulten, Edwin R. Dean, and Michael J. Harper
(eds.), New Developments in Productivity Analysis, Chicago: University of Chicago
Press, 2001, 103-64.
Norsworthy, John R. and Show-Ling Jang, “Cost Function Estimation of Quality Change
in Semiconductors,” in Murray F. Foss, Marilyn E. Mansor, and Allen H. Young (eds.),
Price Measurements and Their Uses, Chicago: Chicago University Press, 1993, 125-55.
Ohta, Makoto, “Production Technologies of the U.S. Boiler and Turbo Generator
Industries and Hedonic Price Indexes for Their Products: A Cost-Function Approach,”
Journal of Political Economy, 83(1), February 1975, 1-26.
29
Oliner, Stephen D. and Daniel E. Sichel, “The Resurgence of Growth in the Late 1990s:
Is Information Technology the Story?” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 14(4), Fall
2000, 3-22.
Oliveira-Martins,-Joaquim, Stefano Scarpetta, and Dirk Pilat, “Mark-Up Pricing, Market
Structure and the Business Cycle,” OECD Economic Studies, (27), 1996, 71-105.
Raff, Daniel M. G. and Manuel Trajtenberg, “Quality-Adjusted Prices for the American
Automobile Industry: 1906-1940,” in Timothy F. Bresnahan and Robert J. Gordon (eds.),
The Economics of New Good, Chicago: University of Chicago Press, 1997, 71-101.
Rosen, Sherwin, “Hedonic Prices and Implicit Markets: Product Differentiation in Pure
Competition,” Journal of Political Economy, 82(1), January-February 1974, 34-55.
Stavins, Joanna, “Model Entry and Exit in a Differentiated-Product Industry: The
Personal Computer Market,” Review of Economics and Statistics, 77(4), November 1995,
571-84.
Stavins, Joanna, “Estimating Demand Elasticities in a Differentiated Product Industry:
The Personal computer Market,” Journal of Economics and Business, 49(4), July-August
1997, 347-67.
Thompson, Peter and Doug Waldo, “Process versus Product Innovation: Do
Consumption Data Contain Any Information?” Southern Economic Journal, 67(1), July
2000, 155-70.
Warnke, Jacqueline, “Computer Manufacturing: Change and Competition,” Monthly
Labor Review, 119(8), August 1996, 18-29.
Whelan, Karl, “Computers, Obsolescence, and Productivity,” Review of Economics and
Statistics, 84(3), August 2002, 445-61.
Yorukoglu, Mehmet, “Product vs. Process Innovations and Economic Fluctuations,”
Carnegie-Rochester Conference Series on Public Policy, 52(1), June 2000, 137-63.
30
Table 1. Summary Statistics: 1978-1999
(Average annual growth rates in percentage)
Electronic Computer Computer Computer
computers storage terminals peripheral Average
devices equipment
(3571) (3572) (3575) (3577)
Outputs
Nominal output 10.20 11.08 0.84 9.17 9.91
List price -5.51 -2.20 -4.04 -5.37 -4.93
Hedonic price -20.47 -8.59 -8.37 -12.85 -16.87
Quantity of output 15.71 13.28 4.88 14.54 14.83
Quality of output 14.96 6.38 4.34 7.48 11.95
Inputs
Quantity of labor input -0.38 1.93 -4.76 2.32 0.39
Quantity of materials 16.14 16.06 6.46 14.71 15.65
Quantity of capital stock 6.65 9.80 4.58 8.80 7.51
Price of labor input 5.45 4.83 4.30 5.65 5.38
Price of materials -5.00 -4.81 -4.59 -4.83 -4.92
Rental price of capital stock 2.16 2.29 2.28 2.26 2.21
Note: Average growth rates of the four industries are weighted by the industry share of nominal output
between two adjacent years. The growth rate of output quantity is equal to the growth rate of nominal
output minus the growth rate of list price. The growth rate of output quality is equal to the growth rate of
list price minus the growth rate of hedonic price.
31
Table 2. Estimation Results
Parameter Estimate Standard Error
Β0 6.4820 0.4521
Β02 (dummy) -1.9822 0.2256
Β03 (dummy) -1.8254 0.3105
Β04 (dummy) -0.5309 0.1985
BL 0.8703 0.1124
ΒL2 (dummy) 0.0336 0.0152
ΒL3 (dummy) 0.0074 0.0297
ΒL4 (dummy) 0.0230 0.0139
ΒK 0.0982 0.0771
ΒK2 (dummy) -0.0464 0.0151
ΒK3 (dummy) -0.1058 0.0303
ΒK4 (dummy) -0.0222 0.0141
ΒQ 0.5496 0.0882
ΒQ2 (dummy) -0.0544 0.0248
ΒQ3 (dummy) -0.0164 0.0404
ΒQ4 (dummy) -0.0727 0.0206
ΒS 0.4737 0.0696
ΒS2 (dummy) -0.0498 0.0190
ΒS3 (dummy) -0.0384 0.0308
ΒS4 (dummy) -0.0682 0.0162
ΒT -0.1642 0.0270
ΒT2 (dummy) 0.0910 0.0069
ΒT3 (dummy) 0.0710 0.0105
ΒT4 (dummy) 0.0473 0.0061
ΒLL 0.0939 0.0312
ΒKK -0.0815 0.0135
ΒQQ 0.0012 0.0102
ΒSS 0.0089 0.0059
ΒTT 0.0018 0.0008
ΒLK 0.0000 0.0134
ΒLQ -0.0235 0.0080
ΒLE -0.0208 0.0061
ΒLT -0.0128 0.0026
ΒKQ 0.0419 0.0073
ΒKS 0.0142 0.0048
ΒKT -0.0001 0.0014
ΒQS 0.0087 0.0072
ΒQT 0.0007 0.0019
ΒST 0.0010 0.0014
AQ -0.3275 0.0336
AS 0.5236 0.0270
Equation Standard Error R2
Variable cost equation 0.0847 0.9957
Labor share equation 0.0205 0.9069
Capital share equation 0.0213 0.5192
Output quantity equation 0.0686 0.6236
Output quality equation 0.0688 0.6213
32
Table 3. Short-run and Long-run Cost Elasticities and Scales
Electronic Computer Computer Computer
computers storage terminals peripheral Average
devices equipment
(3571) (3572) (3575) (3577)
Short-run
Quantity of output 0.909 0.804 0.774 0.786 0.864
Quality of output 0.708 0.626 0.603 0.612 0.673
Time -0.101 -0.011 -0.032 -0.055 -0.077
Price of labor input 0.227 0.300 0.308 0.281 0.251
Price of materials 0.773 0.700 0.692 0.719 0.749
Capital stock -0.093 -0.120 -0.109 -0.073 -0.092
Scale 1.100 1.245 1.291 1.272 1.163
Long-run
Quantity of output 0.833 0.718 0.698 0.733 0.791
Quality of output 0.648 0.559 0.544 0.571 0.616
Time -0.092 -0.010 -0.029 -0.051 -0.070
Price of labor input 0.207 0.268 0.278 0.262 0.229
Price of materials 0.709 0.624 0.624 0.671 0.687
Scale 1.202 1.394 1.432 1.365 1.271
Note: Average elasticities and scales of the four industries are weighted by the industry share of nominal
output between two adjacent years.
33
Table 4. Decompositions of TFP Growth in Computer Industries: 1978-1999
(in percentage)
Electronic Computer Computer Computer
computers storage terminals peripheral Average
devices equipment
(3571) (3572) (3575) (3577)
TFP growth rate 18.46 8.00 6.00 10.91 15.06
Scale effect 2.76 3.83 1.38 3.87 3.12
Effect of product innovation 5.08 2.76 2.01 3.18 4.30
Effect of process innovation 9.24 0.97 2.86 5.10 7.03
Residuals 1.38 0.44 -0.26 -1.24 0.60
Industry output share 0.62 0.13 0.03 0.22
Note: Average rates of the four industries are weighted by the industry share of nominal output between
two adjacent years.
34
Table 5. Contribution of the Computer Industry to TFP Growth
in the Nonfarm Business Sector
1978-1990 1991-1995 1996-1999 1978-1999
TFP growth rate in the nonfarm business sector:
BLS (2001) 0.30 0.60 1.10 0.51
TFP growth rate in the computer industry:
Oliner and Sichel (2000) 11.2a 11.3 16.6 12.2b
This study 13.98 12.37 22.05 15.06
Domar weight of the computer industry:
Oliner and Sichel (2000) 1.1a 1.4 1.6 1.2b
This study 1.42 1.35 1.64 1.45
Contribution from the computer industry to TFP growth in the nonfarm business sector:
Oliner and Sichel (2000) 0.12a 0.16 0.26 0.15b
This study
Total contribution 0.19 0.17 0.37 0.22
Scale effect 0.05 0.03 0.02 0.04
Effect of product innovation 0.04 0.05 0.17 0.07
Effect of process innovation 0.10 0.09 0.11 0.10
Residuals 0.00 -0.01 0.07 0.01
Notes: Domar weight is defined as the ratio of gross output in the computer industry to value-added in the
nonfarm business sector.
a
includes the period of 1974-1990.
b
includes the period of 1974-1999.
35
Figure 1. Contribution from the Computer Industry to TFP Gorwth in the Nonfarm Business Sector
0.60
0.50
Total Contribution
0.40 Product innovation
0.30
Process innovation
0.20
0.10
0.00
Scale effect
-0.10
-0.20
1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999
36